Preface
The Expert Group on Public Finance, or ESO (Swedish acronym for “Expertgruppen för studier i offentlig ekonomi”) is an ad hoc independent government commission attached to the Swedish Ministry of Finance. ESO was formed in 1981. Its main objective is to make sure that public resources are used more efficiently and to scrupulously evaluate public expenditure systems as well as economic effects of revenue collected. In recent years, however, the focus of ESO has become increasingly international and devoted to international comparisons such as benchmarking and analyses of different sectors concerning the consequences of Sweden joining the European Union. This report belongs to the latter category.
Firstly, however, a few words to clarify the status of the ESO Reports. ESO studies are normally carried out by academic researchers, individual civil servants, research institutions, and specialized agencies under contract to ESO. Our studies are defined as reports to and not by ESO; the views, findings, and suggestions are the exclusive responsibility of the authors; neither by ESO itself nor the Ministry of Finance.
The first stage of the process of enlarging the European Union is now drawing to a close, the perspective being that candidate countries should be able to join the European Union as of 2004. Much of the debate, particularly in the last phase of the negotiations, has focused on the costs of the enlargement during the first few years. Much energy has been devoted to issues concerning the costs of the support to agriculture in the new member states, structural support and budgetary compensations in order to facilitate the integration of the new members in the financial system before 2006 when the present Financial Perspective for the European Union expires.
ESO has issued this study as a contribution to a wider discussion, mainly by identifying some of the issues that must be tackled in the not so distant future. The work has been carried out, at the request of ESO, by Bengt O. Karlsson, M.Sc. from the
3
Stockholm School of Economics, a former head of the
In budgetary terms the brunt of the enlargement costs will fall in the period after 2006. The author finds that those costs are likely to be manageable and that the savings potential, also through relatively modest reforms of the agricultural and structural policies, is large. But he also shows that the present system of financing and allocating budgetary expenditure within the Union will lead to an even more uneven distribution of the financial burden after the enlargement than is presently the case. The main reason for this is the financial concessions given to a small number of contributors through successive decisions of the European Council. The study discusses some elements that could be included in a reformed financing system – an issue that should be tackled by the ongoing Convention on the Future of Europe as well as the Intergovernmental Conference.
The study claims that new inequalities between the member states will appear after the enlargement and the risk for an erosion of the Union is apparent. At the end of the study the author asks whether a political and economic entity that spans from Luxembourg (the country with the highest GDP/capita) or Sweden (the country with the highest rank in UNDP’s Human Development index) to Albania or Moldova really can function. It will be up to the Intergovernmental Conference to show the political courage to take the necessary decisions, which must transgress national interests in order to ensure that the European unification process will lead to the conditions of peace and prosperity which no doubt were in the mind of the European leaders when the enlargement process started in 1993.
By issuing this study ESO hopes to have made a modest contribution to the discussion on the future of Europe.
Stockholm, October 2002
Leni Björklund
Chairman of ESO
4
Author’s preface
The preparations for the enlargement of the European Union by 10 to 12 new members are nearing completion. It is expected that the final decision on membership will be taken at the meeting of the European Council in Copenhagen in December 2002. This would enable candidate countries to join as new members as of 2004.
The enlargement will have a profound influence on the European Union. This study tries to make a contribution to an understanding of some issues that need to be discussed and agreed on before the end of 2006 when the current financial framework for the EU expires. It does so mainly by investigating the
The author would like to thank the members of the secretariat of the Swedish Expert Group on Public Finance (ESO) for their support during the writing of the study. I am particularly grateful to the staff of the EU Division of the Budget Department of the Swedish Ministry of Finance for their cooperation, based on so much experience and knowledge of EU matters. (In view of our close cooperation I should perhaps state explicitly that conclusions, opinions and statements in this study in no way may be regarded as official Swedish positions). A special Reference Group within ESO consisting of Swedish and international independent experts has given valuable advice in the course of the work. Needless to say, all remaining errors and shortcomings are entirely my own responsibility.
The work on the study was finalized by August 31. Accordingly, it has not been possible to consider events, data or documents of a later date.
The most successful attempt to unify Europe prior to the EU was at its high point around the year 800 A.D. A great European
5
author and Nobel Laureate wrote about the people of Europe at that time:
”Sur une feuille de tremble nul ne peut vivre en sécurité. Pourtant y vivent d’infimes créatures, ignorantes que leur pays est une feuille de tremble. Elle n’en constitue pas moins leur séjour, leur patrie dans un monde, le monde des feuilles de tremble1.”
Alas, the world of aspen leaves created by Charlemagne soon crumbled to pieces. Let us hope we do better this time!
Vienna and Stockholm, September 2002
Bengt O. Karlsson
1 (Quote from: Eyvind Johnson: Hans Nådes Tid. French translation Le Temps de Sa Grâce, Lausanne, 2000. With permission from Editions ESPRIT OUVERT.)
6
Contents
1 | Summary | 13 |
1.1 | The study in a nutshell | 13 |
1.2 | Purpose of the study | 14 |
1.3The scenario analysis and macroeconomic
effects | 15 |
1.4Burden sharing and need for reforms of the
financial system | 18 | |
1.5 | An erosion of the union? | 19 |
2 | Introduction: Issues and methods | 21 |
Part 1. The road to enlargement | 25 | |
3 | Towards a larger union | 25 |
3.1 | The framework | 25 |
3.2 | The process | 27 |
3.3 | Enlargement, yes, but who will pay? | 29 |
4 | A larger union: costs and resources | 31 |
4.1 | What will the enlargement cost? | 31 |
4.2 | Financing the enlargement costs | 35 |
4.3 | The macroeconomic impact | 38 |
5 | Post 2006: Time to pay the bill! | 45 |
5.1 | A |
46 |
5.1.1 The characteristics of the bechmark | ||
scenario | 46 | |
5.1.2 The relation between payments and | ||
expenditure | 47 | |
5.2 | A Least Resistance scenario | 48 |
5.2.1 Assumptions | 48 | |
5.2.2 Results of the Least Resistance | ||
Scenario | 49 | |
5.2.3 The importance of growth | 50 |
7
5.2.4 The importance of the time profile of | ||
accession | 52 | |
5.2.5 Budgetary compensation to new | ||
member states | 53 | |
5.2.6 Summary of the impact on costs of | ||
enlargement without policy | ||
reforms | 54 | |
6 | Enlargement costs in reform scenarios | 57 |
6.1 | Cutting costs through policy reforms | 57 |
6.1.1 A less expensive agricultural policy | 57 | |
6.1.2 Structural policy: same rules for all? | 62 | |
6.2 | Summary of the cost estimates | 66 |
6.2.1 A recap of our scenarios | 66 | |
6.2.2 What other studies say | 69 | |
6.3 | Is there a worse scenario? | 70 |
Part 2. Equity in a large union | 73 | |
7 | Sharing the financial burden | 73 |
7.1 | The issue of budgetary imbalances | 73 |
7.2 | Burden sharing in EU 15 | 75 |
7.3The share of new member states in the
financial burden | 77 |
7.4Changes in the burden sharing in different
scenarios | 80 | |
8 | Burden sharing – reform issues | 85 |
8.1 | The UK rebate | 85 |
8.2 | Reforms of the Own Resources System | 88 |
8.3 | What is relative prosperity? | 91 |
8.4Partial
8.5Towards a more equitable burden sharing in
a larger EU | 96 |
8
9 | An eroded union? | 101 |
9.1The candidate countries are small with a very
low level of income | 101 |
9.2Are the candidate countries more developed
than national account numbers seem to | ||
indicate? | 104 | |
9.3 | The invisible problems | 107 |
Appendix 1: Net positions and ability to pay | 111 | |
Appendix 2: Additional tables | 115 | |
Terms used | 121 | |
Selected www.links | 126 | |
References | 129 | |
List of ESO Reports in English | 133 |
Tables
1.Resources earmarked for enlargement according to the Financial Perspective and the Common
Financial Framework. | 33 |
2.Total budgetary costs (payments) of the EU
by the Commission. | 35 |
3.Financing the EU Budget by different groups of
countries. | 38 | |
4. | Macroeconomic impact of EU enlargement. | |
Total increase of GDP by 2006 and 2010. | 40 |
5.Comparison between macroeconomic gains and
shares of budget of EU 15 countries by 2007. | 42 |
6.Enlargement costs in a Least Resistance Scenario. 50
7.Enlargement costs in the Least Resistance
Scenario with different growth assumptions. | 51 | |
8. | Enlargement costs in the Least Resistance | |
Scenario with different time profiles for | ||
accession. | 53 |
9
9.Enlargement costs and total payments after
enlargement in various scenarios. | 56 | |
10. | Impact of a reduction of agricultural | |
expenditure on enlargement costs. | 60 | |
11. | Impact of different alternatives for structural | |
operations policy on enlargement costs. | 65 | |
12. | Summary of enlargement costs in different | |
scenarios. | 67 | |
13. | Total payments to the EU budget in different | |
enlargement scenarios. | 68 | |
14. | Financial burden sharing in EU 15 in the | |
year 2000. | 77 | |
15. | Net positions 2013 as a share of GNP/GDP | |
in 3 different scenarios. | 80 | |
16. | Net positions 2013 under a generalized net | |
correction system. | 87 | |
17. | Total payments 2013 in a |
|
payments system. | 90 | |
18. | Payments and net positions 2013 in a system | |
based on purchasing power parities. | 92 |
19.The relation between member countries shares
of allocated expenditure and of payments | ||
in 2000. | 95 | |
20. | Share of the candidate countries in an | |
enlarged EU. | 102 | |
21. | GDP per capita in candidate countries in | |
relation to EU 15. | 103 |
Appendix tables
1.Net positions in 2013 calculated with different
definitions. | 114 | |
2. | The benchmark scenario (no enlargement), | |
commitments and payments. | 116 | |
3. | Enlargement costs by country group in a Least | |
Resistance Scenario. | 117 | |
4. | Total payments to the EU budget by country | |
group in a Least Resistance Scenario. | 117 | |
5. | Net positions by country group in a Least | |
Resistance Scenario. | 118 | |
6. | Distribution of payments and receipts in | |
EU15 in 2006 including enlargement costs. | 119 | |
10 |
Charts
1.Net positions of Net Payers in the Least
Resistance Scenario |
82 |
2.Net positions of Net Receivers
in the Least Resistance Scenario | 83 |
Note 1
Both GNP and GDP play an operational role in the context of the EU budget. Payments are partly calculated in relation to the GNP whereas the distribution of structural funds and the
Note 2
Unless otherwise specified all calculations of budgetary costs refer to appropriations for payments. The meaning and significance of this term is explained in several instances, notable in sections 5.1.2 and in section Terms used.
Note 3
All calculations, without exception, are carried out and expressed at constant prices, at the price level of 1999.
Note 4
Publications and documents from the European Commission and from the Council of the European Union are referred to as “EC” in the text. In the List of References those documents are listed in chronological order.
11
12
1 Summary
1.1The study in a nutshell
The purpose of this study is twofold. The first purpose is to make quantitative estimates of the budgetary costs of the enlargement of the EU, estimates which assume on the one hand that no changes will be made to the present system for financing and allocating expenditure and on the other that the EU agricultural and/or structural policy will be reformed in the period after 2006 when the present
The main finding of the study is that the significant share of the enlargement costs will come in the period after 2006, that is to say during a period which is not yet under active consideration by the responsible parties. Even then, however, the costs will be manageable and certainly within the framework that the EU member countries implicitly or explicitly must have taken into account when they decided in 1993 to start the enlargement process. In addition, reforms of agricultural and structural polices, which are badly required for the functioning of the market, its efficiency and competitiveness, will offer considerable scope for savings. Should the economic growth of the Union slow down considerably for a long period the picture would be different and more troubling.
The
13
financial system, which make the distribution of financial burdens unequal. The root of those problems is on the one hand an outdated system for estimating and distributing annual payments from the member countries and on the other hand the special financial advantages that were granted to the UK in 1984 and to Germany, Sweden, Austria and the Netherlands in 1999 (to be applied from 2002 onwards). The end result is that any increase in costs, for instance for the enlargement, will have a proportionally larger impact on other net payers but also on the cohesion countries in EU 15 and on the new member states. Already this calls for a thorough reform of the payments system.
Other risk factors for the
1.2Purpose of the study
The first purpose of this study is to estimate, in quantitative terms, the budgetary cost of the enlargement of the European Union including the costs of alternatives to the present agricultural, structural and other polices. We will also make a cursory comparison between the costs of enlargement and the corresponding macroeconomic gains or losses.
The second purpose of the study is to identify possible future tensions and points of diverging interests between groups of countries and draw tentative conclusions as to reforms required to minimize those divergences. Our starting point will be that most of the reform requirements are already present in the Union but will be aggravated and inevitable once the enlargement process has taken its course.
14
1.3The scenario analysis and macroeconomic effects
At the time of writing accession negotiations with 10 out of 12 candidate countries are drawing to a close. The goal is that a decision to accept those countries as new members of the Union as of 2004 will be taken by the European Council in Copenhagen in December 2002.
The Financial Perspective for the period
For the period after 2006 this study uses a
15
How will contributions and net positions of present and future member countries develop in various hypothetical enlargement scenarios?
The main enlargement scenario that we are testing is called the Least Resistance Scenario. We assume that there will be no reform of agricultural policy after 2006 and that the Commission’s proposal for phasing in direct support payments to new member states to 100 % by 2013 is implemented. For structural operations we make the technical assumption that the same rules for allocation of funds will be applied to all member countries. Since this would imply drastic losses of structural funds for the present membership and in particular the cohesion countries (Greece, Spain, Portugal and Ireland) we have made a supplementary assumption that all EU 15 countries will continue to receive the same amounts as they did in 2006. We have also assumed that
We can safely say that the assumptions behind the Least Resistance Scenario come close to a
Sensitivity analysis shows that if the
16
What will be the budgetary impact of reform alternatives for the future agricultural and structural policy?
A reform of the agricultural policy of the EU, which were to take the form of a phasing down of direct support costs to 85 % of the present level by 2013, would mean that the enlargement costs (net) would reach 0.18 % of GNP of the enlarged Union by 2013 against 0.23 % in the Least Resistance Scenario. The strict application of same rules for all member states in the field of structural policy would produce even more drastic cost cuts: instead of the 0.23 %, enlargement costs (net) would amount only to 0.11 % of the GNP of the enlarged Union by 2013.
We believe that none of those alternatives is entirely realistic in the form we have estimated them. But the results indicate a considerable savings potential that could be exploited in negotiations and agreements.
Our calculations are by and large supported by evidence from other, similar, international studies. Studies that have taken an econometric approach, however, generally come out with higher cost estimates since they do not take full account of the change in expenditure trends achieved in Agenda 2000. All our estimates are based on an assumption that that trend change will be sustained up to 2013.
How do the additional budgetary costs relate to the macroeconomic impact of enlargement?
Other studies show that we can expect small, but significant positive macroeconomic effects in the present EU 15 countries (possibly with some exceptions) and very large ones in the new member states. Even in purely economic terms the enlargement would thus be a net gain for the European Union.
17
1.4Burden sharing and need for reforms of the financial system
How will enlargement effect the distribution of the financial burden between member countries?
Sweden, Germany, the Netherlands and Austria are the largest net payers to the Union in relative terms (as share of GNP or per capita). Whereas our extrapolations show that the net position of those countries will continue to deteriorate they will benefit from a certain dampening effect, due to the financing arrangement agreed in Berlin 1999. The same is true, obviously, for the UK but not for a group of net payers consisting of France, Italy, Denmark and Finland, which increasingly will emerge as substantive net payers. (France is already a net payer.) New member states will benefit from very large inflows of budgetary funds and the net positions will improve dramatically for all countries, but particularly for the Baltic countries and for Romania and Bulgaria. There are three exceptions: Slovenia, Malta and Cyprus, which may even become net payers, at least in the beginning of their membership.
The inequities of the present system are made even clearer if we try to look at the countries’ real ability to pay by using purchasing power parities (ppp) instead of
How could the system for financing budgetary expenditure become more equitable and sustainable in the long term?
In order to eliminate or reduce the inequities of the present system we suggest a new system, based mainly on
18
countries that met certain
1.5An erosion of the union?
In the final chapter of the study we discuss the situation of the new member states from a different point of view. First we note that whereas the population of 12 candidate countries would constitute 22 % of the population of the enlarged EU, their contribution to the GNP, and thereby to the budget, would be only around 4 %. We see also that the income difference to the present EU countries is far greater than it has been in earlier enlargements. This is true whether we measure at official exchange rates or at purchasing power parities, it is true whether we compare with the EU 15 average or with the lowest ranked member country in EU 15. In 1999 the income level in Romania (at official exchange rates) was 7 % of the EU 15 average and 13 % of the level in Greece or Portugal. For a relatively wealthy and developed country as Poland the corresponding numbers were 18 % and 35 %. Figures for the island states and Slovenia are better and might be comparable to Portugal and Greece at the time for their accession, at least if we make the comparison at purchasing power parities. But generally the differences are enormous.
Looking at available index data for human development and international competitiveness there are some glimpses of light: some candidate countries may have latent human resources that not yet have had full impact on the potential
19
Other authors have pointed to the risk for an erosion of the Union through the enlargement. National interests and national exceptions may become more and more prevalent. The negotiations have created a plethora of special national exceptions from the common rules and certain inroads have been made into the basic freedoms for the movements of people, goods, service and capital. Certainly, these are to be temporary measures. The screening of the acquis communautaire focuses on the number of institutions and legislative and administrative measures that have been implemented. Whether the successful implementation of the acquis in this, formal, sense also has given the new members the possibility to keep pace with the European integration process remains to be seen. If this capacity is deficient and if other countries would like to forge ahead with the flexible integration provided for in the Treaty of Nice tension and gaps within the enlarged union may create problems of a much higher dignity than the ones related to the budgetary costs.
20
2 Introduction: Issues and methods
The first purpose of this study is to estimate, in quantitative terms, the cost of the enlargement of the European Union, that is to say the budgetary costs for the member states and for the Union itself. The costs of alternatives to the present agricultural, structural and other polices will also be analyzed.
Estimates will be made for each one of the present members of the EU as well as for future member states. The study will focus on the contributions to the EU budget and on the distribution of the financial burden between the member countries and the new member states, that is to say their contributions as well as the allocation of resources from the EU budget. We will also make a cursory comparison between the costs of enlargement and the corresponding macroeconomic gains or losses, both for the present and the new member states. These issues are covered by part 1 of the study.
Part 2 of the study is devoted to the second purpose, which is to identify possible future tensions and points of diverging interests between groups of countries and draw tentative conclusions as to reforms required to minimize those divergences. Our starting point will be that most of the reform requirements are already present in the Union but will be aggravated and inevitable once the enlargement process has taken its course.
The study will try to answer questions such as:
N How will the contributions and the net positions (contributions less allocations from the budget) of the present and future member countries develop in various hypothetical scenarios for the enlargement?
N What will be the budgetary impact of different alternatives for the future agricultural and structural policy and for possible concessions to new members concerning the payments of contributions?
21
N How do the additional budgetary costs relate to the macroeconomic impact of enlargement?
N What will be the impact on the distribution of the financial burden of the enlargement between member countries?
N Which reform elements can be identified for financing budgetary expenditure, which would contribute to a more equitable system, sustainable over the long term?
Our analysis of the first two questions will be a static one since we cannot consider the feedback effect from changing macroeconomic conditions due to the enlargement, for instance increased growth in the Union. Some results from other studies are, however, presented in section 4.3. The study does not at all go into the difficult and intricate issue of monetary cooperation and the common currency. Membership of the EMU, with its special criteria for eligibility, is foreseen for new member states.
The budgetary cost implications of the enlargement were already analyzed in the study Priset för ett större EU – en
The estimates have been made by means of a model2 based on MS Excel®, simulating the
2 The model is not an economic model, stricto sensu, since it consists of a large number of identities without any estimated behavioral functions. Even if the ”model” is large and relatively complicated, it must be regarded mainly as an accounting device or ”calculator”. However, it appears that the terminological stringency in this respect has become rather blurred nowadays, which is why we take the liberty of using the term ”model” in this study. Nevertheless, we define our approach as an ”accountancy approach” in contrast to the econometric studies to which we will refer at a later stage.
22
instance concerning total costs, rebates for new members, the costs for the agricultural or the structural policy etc.
The allocation of funds from the
In addition to the questions listed above, there are other issues that merit a profound discussion. The Union will change profoundly after enlargement. The membership will almost double (from 15 to 27) and all of the new member states are in many respects very different from the present membership. This goes for the level of economic development and the economic structure but is true also in other ways. Most of the new members are very young democracies with a short experience of the market economy and the related economic, administrative and social policies. This may create difficulties for the continued integration, particularly if some member states would like to forge ahead, making use of the possibilities of flexible integration, provided by the Treaty of Nice. The fact that the new member states, even taken together, will be a very small share of the EU economy will facilitate the integration process – the enormous gap between most of the new member states and the present ones will make the process more difficult. These issues are discussed in the final chapter of the study.
23
24
Part 1. The road to enlargement
3 Towards a larger union
3.1The framework
The enlargement of the European Union to embrace a number of previously socialist Eastern European countries, including parts of the former Soviet Union, is a historic occurrence and may well be a decisive step towards the unification of Europe.
This enlargement process started in 1993 when the European Council, at a meeting in Copenhagen, resolved that associated countries in Central and Eastern Europe could become full members of the EU if they so wished. Accession could take place as soon as a country fulfilled the political and economic requirements for membership. At present, accession negotiations are going on with 12 candidate countries, including the Mediterranean island states Cyprus and Malta. Turkey has also attained status of official candidate country but negotiations have not yet started. For 10 of the candidate countries negotiations are drawing to a close, the supposition being that the final decision on membership would be taken in Copenhagen in December 2002. It is a rational assumption that the number of EU members will have increased from 15 to 25 by 2004 or 2005 and to 27 before the end of the present decade.
At the outset, Eastern enlargement was strongly supported by most of the present member states. With time, attitudes have become more multifaceted among and within the member countries. After the Gothenburg Summit in June 2001 the enlargement again gained political momentum and although some stumbling blocks have appeared and negotiations on some of the major issues have not yet started at the time of writing, the enlargement remains the strongest political priority for the Union. The motives of the present member states for supporting the enlargement of the union may be varied but the wish to create lasting peace and security on the European continent is without
25
doubt the
The strong will from almost all quarters to see a rapid enlargement of the Union cannot, however, hide a large number of worries, threats and misgivings, less from individual member states than from groups, regions or sectors within some of the member countries. The year 2002 will show us whether any of those misgivings will transform into real stumbling blocks on the road to enlargement. Another factor of uncertainty appears to be the public opinion in some of the candidate countries: if opinion polls give any indication at all, the outcome of the referenda that will be held is by no means certain.3
Even without enlargement there would be many fundamental issues, which need to be tackled by the European Union over the next few years such as policy reforms (mainly in the fields of agriculture and structural support), institutional reforms and reform of the system of financing the budget of the Union. A special convention on the future of Europe is presently working and will present its findings and proposal by June 2003. An Intergovernmental Conference will be convened later in 2003 or in 2004 to take the necessary decisions on the future of the European Union.
The enlargement process, which includes negotiations, accession of new members, implementation of transitional arrangements and continued negotiations with remaining, and possibly new, candidate countries, coincides with this period of necessary reform and change in the Union. In the midst of it all, a new
3 Another uncertainty factor is that the Treaty of Nice, which is a prerequisite for the enlargement, has been rejected by Ireland in a referendum. A scond referendum on the issue will be held in October 2002.
26
It is easy to see that all those issues, including the integration of a large number of new member states, are closely interrelated. Yet, so high is the priority of the enlargement, that it has been, and still is, an unbreakable taboo for the Commission as well as for member states and candidate countries to link the enlargement negotiations to the reform issues. A few attempts to link enlargement and the future of the common agricultural policy have quickly been quenched. One practical, and perhaps intended, consequence of this
We can thus begin to discern a perspective where the most critical and difficult issues, particularly the financial ones, will loom large in a period which is not yet under active consideration, at least not explicitly, by the responsible parties. We will show in this study that the budgetary costs of enlargement will become significant only after 2006 but we will also argue that the absorption of those costs is not the most important risk for the future development of the Union and of European integration.
3.2The process
As mentioned above, the enlargement process was initiated in 1993 by a decision of the European Council. The accession should take place as soon as a candidate country met the required economic and political conditions.
The European Council established at the time what became known as the Copenhagen criteria for the fulfillment of the economic and political conditions of membership. Those criteria are mainly that the candidate countries must have stable institutions, which will guarantee democracy, law, human rights and protection of minorities, a functioning market economy that they can compete within the Union and have the ability to meet the obligations of membership. The latter includes an obligation to participate in the political, economic and monetary union. Furthermore, criteria were established for the administrative and institutional structures and for the acceptance of the EU legislation. In order to become members the candidate countries must accept the
27
the Union in the form of treaties, legislation, international agreements etc. This refers mainly to what can be called the basic law of the EU, that is to say the treaties of Rome, Maastricht and Amsterdam.
At its meeting in Luxembourg in December 1997, the European Council decided to start negotiation with Cyprus, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Poland and Slovenia. At a subsequent meeting in Helsinki in December 1999 the Council further decided to start negotiations with Bulgaria, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Romania and Slovakia. At the same time Turkey was recognized as an official candidate country.
It would be taking things too far to go into the details of the negotiation process and the initial screening, the objective of which is to establish to what extent the candidates meet the criteria for membership. The enlargement pages at the website of the Commission4 give a detailed account of the negotiations and the screening. The enlargement strategy paper (EC, 13 November 2001) gives an overview of the situation of the negotiations, in total and for each candidate country as well as the Commission’s proposed time plan for the continued work. The negotiations focus on how and when the candidate countries should introduce the acquis communautaire. The candidate countries often request transitional arrangements, which, however, in the view of the Union, must be of a temporary character. At the time of writing, negotiations have started concerning what is regarded as the most critical chapters namely agricultural policy, regional and structural policy and financing.
At its meeting in Gothenburg on 14 June 2001, the European Council set the objective that those candidate countries which were ready should participate as EU Members in the European Parliament elections of 2004, and should be able to conclude the accession negotiations by the end of 2002. (EC, 13 November 2001).
The basic principles for the conclusion of the negotiations for entry are, according to the Commission’s strategy paper, that each country should be assessed on its own merits and that countries that started negotiations later than others should have the possibility to catch up. For those reasons it is now often assumed that 10 candidate countries will join the Union by 2004. Bulgaria and Romania are slated for a later time of accession. This will be
4 Many of the documents that are referred to in this study are available on the World Wide Web. See ”Selected www links”, below.
28
the main assumption in this study but one alternative scenario will also be explored.
3.3Enlargement, yes, but who will pay?
The enlargement will require considerable financial resources. The level of income in the candidate countries is far below that of the present member countries. It is clear that new members will be entitled to considerable amounts as support to their agricultural sector as well as structural support. At the same time, their ability to contribute to the common budget is relatively low.
At present 9 out of the 15 member states of the EU are net contributors or net payers, that is to say they make larger contributions to the EU budget than the amounts that are allocated to them from the same budget.5 In addition to the presently largest net payers the importance of some other member states as net payers will grow considerably during the period under study. As we will see, it is quite possible that at least one additional net payer will emerge from the candidate countries.
Present and emerging net payers will have to finance the largest part of the costs of enlargement. In the negotiations of Agenda 2000 net payers were quite successful in achieving a reorientation of the budget development in a more restrictive direction than before. Through this reorientation financial room for the enlargement was created. There are several factors at play, however, which may, in the future, exercise an upward pressure on their payments. Present net receivers are not likely to sacrifice their financial benefits easily and may demand compensation for any concession they have to make. Much budgetary authority has been transferred from the Council of Ministers to the European Parliament, which, by tradition, tends to take a more expansionary approach to the budget. One of the richest member countries, the United Kingdom, will continue to contribute a disproportionally low share of the budget and other net payers may demand the same kind of discount that was granted to Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden and Austria in 1999 by the Berlin Council. It may also become necessary to grant new members some kind of phasing in of their membership payments until the inflow of funds from the
5 Applying the
29
EU budget has picked up. Any such concession will have to be financed by the present membership.
Even if the enlargement of the Union has a very high political priority, the goal of budget restrictivity and the necessity to incur direct as well as indirect costs for accommodating new members are obviously conflicting. The question is how serious this conflict of goals will turn out to be, particularly for the net payers, and what the consequences will be for their budgetary contributions. One of the aims of the present study is to illustrate this in quantitative terms.
The financial, or budgetary, contributions must, however, also be weighed against the macroeconomic gains that will result from an enlargement of the Union. There is probably a consensus that those gains will be considerable for the new member countries but what will be the impact on the present membership? Results from some international studies of this issue will be contrasted with our own estimates of the budgetary cost in section 4.3.
The purpose of the enlargement is not, however, to create macroeconomic gains for the members of the Union. The political and social importance of the peace project that is the European Union can hardly be measured in quantitative terms. To leave the Central and Eastern European countries outside the Union would create considerable costs for the Union, both in budgetary and in macroeconomic terms. An unfavorable political, social or economic development in all or some of the present candidate countries could generate costs in monetary, human and political terms, which would be many times greater than the estimated budgetary costs of the enlargement. A
Against the background of the estimates of budgetary costs in this study as well as the calculations of macroeconomic impact of enlargement made by others, it may well be worth asking whether there are other kinds of difficulties connected with the enlargement than those that are manifest in terms of economic costs and benefits. This is done in the last chapter of the study.
30
4A larger union: costs and resources
4.1What will the enlargement cost?
The present chapter will deal with enlargement costs over the period
The development, as usual, took a different turn than originally assumed. It was not possible, and perhaps not even desirable, to finalize negotiations in sufficient time for new members to be accepted already 2002. On the other hand, four additional candidates succeeded in accelerating their adoption of the acquis communautaire to such an extent that they could be considered on equal footing with the first group. Those countries were Latvia, Lithuania, Malta and Slovakia.
Without formally abandoning the
31
The proposal for a Common Financial Framework for Negotiations
In January 2002 the Commission presented an information note on a Common Financial Framework for the Negotiations
We note that despite the fact that enlargement costs are now included for 10 countries instead of the 6 that were foreseen in Berlin, payments for the period 2004 – 2006 are estimated at 0.10 % of GNP in EU 15 instead of the 0.13 % of the Financial Perspective. It has been argued, however, that the comparison should not be made with the calendar years 2004 – 2006 but with the first three years of accession. Taken at face value, the costs of 0.10 % of GNP estimated by the CFF should then be compared with a Berlin cost estimate of 0.08 % of the GNP of EU 15 (not shown in the table). The additional cost of 0.02 % of GNP (or an absolute amount of 8.2 billion Euro)6 would represent the cost of the additional four countries as well as of additional measures that were not foreseen in Berlin. The most important of the latter is the inclusion of a certain amount of direct support to the agricultural sector in new member states.
However, the issue of various possible comparisons with the Berlin agreement is a purely academic one by now. The discussion has instead come to focus on issues like:
N Will the proposed resources be enough to ensure an equal treatment of new and old member states, in particular with respect to the critical issue of direct income support to the agricultural sector?
N Will it be necessary to alleviate the budgetary situation in new members states, given that they will have a low capacity to absorb support from the Union at the beginning of their membership but will have to render full contributions to the EU budget immediately upon accession?
6 Unless otherwise specified all absolute amounts in this study are given in 1999 prices in order to secure consistency with the Financial Perspective, the CFF and various international studies. To obtain current (2002) prices an increase of around 5 % could be applied as a rule of thumb.
32
At the time of writing those questions are the object of an intensive political discussion with candidate countries vehemently protesting that they should have the right to the same level of agricultural support as EU 15 more or less immediately, the Commission insisting on a “take it or leave it” attitude and at least some of the present EU net payers arguing that the proposed framework would imply an undue increase in the financial burden. There are arguments for, and certainly very much against, all those standpoints.
Table 1. Resources earmarked for enlargement according to the Financial Perspective and the Common Financial Framework.
Percentage share of the GNP of EU 15
2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | Total | |
2002- | 2004- | |||||
2006 | 2006 |
Resources earmarked in The Financial Perspecitive 2000 2006 (for 6 countries)
Commitments | 0.08 | 0.11 | 0.13 | 0.16 | 0.18 | 0.13 | 0.16 |
Payments | 0.05 | 0.08 | 0.10 | 0.13 | 0.15 | 0.10 | 0.13 |
Resources proposed in The Common Financial Framework, Jan 2002 (for 10 countries) | |||||||
Commitments | 0.12 | 0.15 | 0.17 | 0.15 | |||
Payments | 0.06 | 0.12 | 0.13 | 0.10 | |||
Source: The Financial Perspective (EC, 1999), the Common Financial Framework (EC, 30.1.2002 ref 9).
Note: The table shows the resources in terms of both commitments and payments. Those terms are explained in the List of Terms. In a simplified way commitments are what member states have promised to pay in a certain financial year, payments what they expect to be really paying. Normally payments follow commitments with a certain time lag.
As can be seen already from table 1, the proposed framework would entail a considerably higher level of commitments over the period
33
the effect of a lack of absorptive capacity of the newcomers. Despite the introduction of the acquis and the
We may conclude that the proposed CFF adds considerably less to the EU budget than was foreseen in Berlin even though 10 countries are now considered and some unforeseen direct support payments to agriculture in new member states have been added. This budgetary space has been created
N by the delay of the enlargement (starting 2004 instead of 2002)
N by budgeting direct support payments only as of 2005 (since claims would be based on production in 2004)
N by assuming that a significantly lower amount than in the Berlin estimates will be required for agricultural market interventions
The last point depends on an assumption of rising world market prices on agricultural products, which would require less intervention on behalf of the European farmers. Agricultural expenditure is
7 The Comission actually now estimates that the cost for market interventions on behalf of new member states would be smaller than half of the amounts included for that purpose in Agenda 2002. The new estimate is less than a third of the amount calculated by the reputed Agricultural Economics Research Institute in the Hague, the Netherlands in April 2001 (Silvis et al., 2001). The Dutch study was, before the proposal by the Commission, the standard material used in estimates of the agricultural enlargement costs
34
Table 2. Total budgetary costs (payments) of the EU 2000 2006 according to official estimates by the Commission.
Percentage shares of the GNP of EU 15
2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | ||
1 | Expenditure for EU 15 and external expenditure | |||||||
According to FP | 1.13 | 1.12 | 1.13 | 1.11 | 1.05 | 1.00 | 0.97 | |
Acc. to outcome and | ||||||||
annual budgets | 0.98 | 1.03 | 0.93 | 1.02 | ||||
2 | Expenditure for the enlargement | |||||||
According to FP | 0.05 | 0.08 | 0.10 | 0.13 | 0.16 | |||
Acc. to CFF | 0.06 | 0.11 | 0.13 | |||||
3 | Total expenditure (=total payments to the EU budget) | |||||||
According to FP | 1.13 | 1.12 | 1.18 | 1.19 | 1.15 | 1.13 | 1.13 | |
Acc. to outcome, budget | ||||||||
and CFF | 0.98 | 1.03 | 0.93 | 1.02. | 1.11 | 1.11 | 1.10 |
Source: EU budgets 2001 and 2001, the Financial Perspective (EC, 1999) and CFF (EC, 30.1.2002, ref 9).
Table 2 summarizes the official estimates of the enlargement costs
4.2 Financing the enlargement costs
In principle, the financing of the total budgetary costs of the EU, including enlargement costs, should be borne loyally and equitably by all EU member states. (EC 1998). However, the UK rebate and the financing advantage from 2002 onwards granted in Berlin 1999 to Germany, Sweden, the Netherlands and Austria represent serious deviations from this principle.
The contributions to the EU budget are regulated by the socalled Own Resources System, which is the implementation of the
8 The meaning and implications of this ceiling are further discussed in footnote 27 below.
35
Own Resources Decision, taken in consensus by the member states. The system is utterly complicated as a result of political considerations and a general unwillingness by the member countries to modify earlier decisions.9 The fact that the system is so complicated may be one reason why earlier studies of the financing of the EU budgets have preferred to work with simplified assumptions of how the financing system works.10 Depending on the purpose of the study such a simplification may be more or less important: when the focus is on the financial burden sharing it will, however, be necessary to look at the details of the financing system. The present study uses a model, which in detail replicates the Own Resources System of the EU in the form it is implemented from the beginning of 2002.
We may make our calculations with a model faithfully representing the financing system of the EU but we mercifully abstain from describing the details of the system. The reader is referred to EC, 1998 for an excellent explanation and evaluation of the system and how it has developed and to EC, 7.10.2000 for details on the new decision, which is being implemented as of 2002.
We recall that the financial resources of the EU are of three types: traditional own resources (mainly custom duties; around 17 % of the total resources in the year 2000),
Despite the fact that both the
9One frequently meets the conception that the obscure dealings of some bureaucracy in Brussels, probably the Commission, unnecessarily complicate and confuse the system of contributions. In our opinion this is not at all the case since the ”bureaucrats” would much prefer to apply a simple and transparent own resources system. Practically all attempts to simplify the system have so far failed because of the stubborn insistence of the member states to retain acquired exceptions and advantageous special modifications and preferably also to introduce new ones to their own benefit. To the extent that a country succeeds in this endeavor it finds it difficult to object to wishes of other members for similar tidbits. One of the more grotesque examples is the mode de calcul of the UK rebate. Another one is that the special financing rebate that four countries will enjoy as of 2002 must, due to the insistence of one member state, be explicitly calculated in the budget by means of two different methods although elementary arithmetic tells us that the end results will be indentical.
10This is, for instance, the case in Quaisser and Hall (2002), which may otherwise be the only other study so far that takes into account the CFF proposed by the Commission.
36
custom duties.11 Another reason is that the size of the
All those rebates and discounts will have to be paid for by the other member states including the new ones. This has as a consequence that the relative contributions to the
The fact the distribution of the financing responsibility is uneven is a structural deficiency of the payment system and as such not a direct consequence of the enlargement. But it means that also the burden of enlargement costs will be unevenly distributed.
11See Appendix 1 for a discussion of those issues, sometimes labled as the Rotterdam effect.
12This is also one of the reasons why it has not been possible to simplify the system and base the whole contribution on GNP. Certain countries, for instance Italy, would have to pay more after such a reform.
13Due to a number of coinciding circumstances the size of the rebate even made the UK a net receiver of budgetary funds in the year 2001. (EC, Allocation of 2001 EU operating expenditure by member state, September 2002.)
37
Table 3. Financing the EU Budget by different groups of countries.
Percentages
Payments to the EU budget
As shares of GNP of | Percentage | |||
each country group | distribution | |||
2002 | 2006 | 2006 | ||
Berlin net payers | Germany, Sweden, Austria, | 1.12 | 1.04 | 33.2 |
the Netherlands | ||||
Net payers without | France, Italy, Denmark, Finland | 1.18 | 1.10 | 35.2 |
rebate | ||||
UK | UK | 0.79 | 0.75 | 12.0 |
Cohesion countries | Ireland, Spain, Portugal, Greece | 1.21 | 1.11 | 11.7 |
EU adm. countries | Belgium, Luxembourg | 1.19 | 1.10 | 3.3 |
New member states | 10 new members | .. | 1.11 | 4.6 |
Total | EU 15 and 25 resp. | 1.10 | 1.02 | 100 |
Source: EU budget 2002 and own estimates.
4.4The macroeconomic impact
Commentators widely agree that the enlargement of the Union will bring about macroeconomic advantages to all or most countries of the enlarged Union. There is also a consensus that there will be large positive effects on the new member states and relatively small ones on the present EU 15 members. Among the latter, countries that are geographically close to the new members generally stand to gain the most whereas a few countries which might be in direct competition with the new member states could even risk making some macroeconomic loss as a result of the enlargement.14
Positive effects would mainly come from the enlargement of the inner market and increased mobility of the factors of production. This would lead to increased growth, higher incomes and employment and – maybe – lower prices because of increased competition. But the positive effects may be distributed in an uneven fashion. Enterprises within the present EU 15 will be subject to increased competition from new member states with
14 See Karlsson, 2001 Ch. 8, for a review and assessment of studies of the macroeconomic impact of enlargement available by the end of 2000. Quaisser and Hall, 2002, contains an updated and systematized list.
38
lower costs and wages. Member states with a large share of branches where labor costs still have a decisive influence on competitive advantages might lose out when industry in the new member states gain improved access to the
In the assessment of available studies made in Karlsson, 2001, only Portugal would effectively stand to lose whereas the impact on Greece and Ireland might be neutral. Countries like Spain and Italy on the other hand would be clear winners and so would the Netherlands.
Newer studies, mainly Breuss, 2001 slightly modify the picture referred to above. Breuss compares two periods
15 Greece and Luxembourg are not included in the study referred to.
39
Table 4. | Macroeconomic impact of EU enlargement. | ||||
Total increase of GDP by 2006 and 2010. | |||||
Cumulative percentages | |||||
Sum of effects from trade, | Sum of effects from factor | ||||
internal markets and budget | movements by: | ||||
costs by: | |||||
2006 | 2010 | 2006 | 2010 | ||
Belgium | 0.36 | 0.48 | |||
Denmark | 0.41 | 0.15 | |||
Germany | 0.64 | 0.37 | 0.11 | ||
Spain | 0.34 | 0.19 | |||
France | 0.18 | 0.35 | |||
Ireland | 0.56 | 0.84 | |||
Italy | 0.51 | 0.62 | |||
Netherlands | 0.74 | 0.44 | |||
Austria | 0.79 | 0.79 | 0.04 | ||
Portugal | 0.67 | 0.05 | |||
Finland | 0.57 | 0.61 | |||
Sweden | 0.69 | 0.07 | 0.01 | ||
United Kingdom | 0.21 | 0.11 | 0.02 | 0.03 | |
Source: Breuss, 2001.
The estimated GNP impact is very small for the EU 15 countries. The data in table 4, are cumulative figures, that is to say the column for 2010 shows the whole
The model calculations by Breuss indicate positive effects from the development of trade and the internal market for all EU 15 countries also after deduction of the negative effects stemming from the budgetary costs. The study is based on a World Global Equilibrium Model. (Even so, only 3 new member states are explicitly treated as well as Eastern Europe as a bloc. Also the assumed time profile of enlargement is slightly different from the one we use in our study.) The model tries to take into account all theoretical effects of the economic integration, including effects of movements of capital and labor. In general the effects of labor migration would be positive for the EU 15 countries, in particular for Austria and Germany. On the other hand, an exogenous assumption that an investment boom in the new member states
16 In principle it would be permissible to add for each year the figures for trade effects and effects of factor movements. We have abstained from this since we assess that the estimated impact of factor movements is much more uncertain than the impact of trade etc. We draw this conclusion mainly from the results of similar studies referred to in the text.
40
would lead to increased interest rates results in mainly negative effects from capital flows in the EU 15 countries. It should be mentioned that Baldwin et al., 1997 do not find such a negative effect despite the fact that the estimated increase in foreign investment in the new member states would be very high. Other studies (see for instance Quaisser, 2000 for a review) show important
We abstain from detailed comments on other similar studies since broadly speaking they concur, always with some exceptions. We can mention, for example, the studies by Dicke and Foders, 2000 as well as by Vaittanen, 2000, which find no positive macroeconomic impacts on the EU 15 countries of the enlargement but only a net financial loss. The main explanation for these deviating results is that in those studies the positive trade effects are assumed to be discounted already. This is certainly a problem. We recall that the
“free trade in industrial products over a gradual, transition period, although the EU opens its markets more quickly than the associated country. As a result, industrial products from the associated countries have had virtually free access to the EU since the beginning of 1995, with restrictions in only a few sectors, such as agriculture and textiles….. In addition to the liberalisation of trade, the Europe Agreements also contain provisions regarding the free movement of services, payments and capital in respect of trade and investments, and the free movement of workers. When establishing and operating in the territory of the other party, enterprises must receive treatment not less favourable than national enterprises.17“
Opinions differ on the extent to which the integration effects have already been discounted in the general liberalization process. Apart from the asymmetry referred to in the quote from the
17 Quote from the web site of the European Commission. See below, Selected www links:
European agreements.
41
Commission18 there are also important exceptions from the agreements, for instance for agricultural products and textiles. In Karlsson, 2001 we ventured the guess that at least half of the macroeconomic impacts had already been accounted for. The study by Breuss, 2001, includes in the results only the macroeconomic effects that are yet to come.
In table 5 we have estimated how the total macroeconomic impact on 13 countries in EU 15 is distributed and also compared each country’s gain with its share of the total EU budget.19 We can also compare that estimate with that of Baldwin et al., 1997.
Table 5. Comparison between macroeconomic gains and shares of budget of EU 15 countries by 2007.
Percentage distribution between countries
Share of |
Share of payments | ||
Derived from Breuss | Derived from Baldwin | to EU | |
Germany | 41.7 | 33.8 | 25.2 |
Italy | 19.2 | 8.5 | 14.9 |
UK | 11.6 | 14.1 | 12.9 |
Netherlands | 6.0 | 4.6 | 5.0 |
Austria | 5.2 | 2.6 | 2.5 |
Sweden | 3.5 | 3.9 | 2.9 |
France | 2.8 | 19.3 | 18.9 |
Belgium | 2.6 | 2.6 | 3.2 |
Finland | 2.5 | 1.4 | 1.7 |
Spain | 2.3 | 7.0 | 8.0 |
Ireland | 1.6 | 0.3 | 1.3 |
Portugal | 1.0 | 1.5 | |
Denmark | 0.0 | 1.9 | 2.2 |
EU 15, total | 100 | 100 | 100 |
Source: Derived from Breuss, 2001 and Baldwin et al., 1997. Own estimates of payments..
If we follow Breuss, 2001, we see that in particular Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Austria and Sweden would benefit from much larger GNP gains than what would correspond to their share of the financing responsibility whereas France and Spain would make smaller gains. Baldwin et al., 1997, on the other hand makes a more
18The EU eliminated tariffs on imports under the European agreement from 1997. The new member states will reach that state only by 2002.
19Obviously it is not permitted to ”net” the shares of GDP gains and of payments. The macroeconomic gains have already been reduced with a negative item caused by enlargement costs. But the table shows, in a sense, the degree of ”fairness” in the distribution of macroeconomic gains.
42
optimistic assessment of those countries but a less optimistic one for Italy.
There are not many studies available of the macroeconomic impact of enlargement in new member states. Commentators agree, however, that the gains will be substantial.
We will see later in our various scenario estimates that the net allocations of EU expenditure to new member states (with the possible exception of Slovenia, Malta and Cyprus) will be very considerable. The inflow would be greatest for the Baltic countries and for Bulgaria and Romania where it would reach 6 % or more of the GNP. For the four Visegrad20 countries the inflow would be somewhat lower but would still approach 4 % towards the end of the period we are studying. We can safely assume that this will have a very strong positive impact on the GDP of those countries.
There are some econometric estimates of the impact on the economies of the new member states. Already Baldwin et al., 1997, estimated an income effect of more than 18 % in seven candidate countries, largely due to increases in foreign investment. Breuss, 2001, finds a positive impact on GDP (average
For one dissenting voice we may quote from a news item from the official Czech news agency that a study assigned by the Slovak Academy of Science will apparently show “an unemployment rate of up to 30 %, a "price shock" and further burden for the
A word must be said about the island states Malta and Cyprus and about Slovenia. Those are the candidate countries with the highest level of income. At the same time they are countries where the agricultural sector plays a smaller role relative to other candidate counties. Their geographical smallness also disqualifies them to a large extent from receiving large amounts of support
20 Poland, Hungary, The Czech Republic and Slovakia. Visegrad (also transcribed as Vysegrad) is a city in nothern Hungary and was in medieval times the seat of Hungarian kings. At a meeting in 1335 a cooperation pact was struck in Visegrad between Bohemia, Hungary and Poland. Well aware of the historical significance, the presidents Havel and Walesa and Prime Minister Antall launched the present cooperation pact in 1991. After the split Slovakia joined as a fourth member.
21 In another study under the auspices of IIASA, Fidrmuc and Fidrmuc, 2000, estimate a positive lift of the Slovak economy of at least 5 % by 2010 in the case of early accession.
43
from structural or cohesion funds. The end result is that they might end up as net contributors to the Union, at least in the beginning of their membership until the flow of funds picks up. It should be stressed that in addition to a possible budgetary compensation, the criteria for distribution of structural support could still be subject to negotiations. The results of our estimates are mainly a consequence of our applying the rules of the present system to the new member countries as well.
44
5 Post 2006: Time to pay the bill!
The resources earmarked for enlargement costs
Chapters 4 to 6 focus on the payments (contributions) to the expanded
Unless otherwise specified, it is assumed in all these scenarios that 10 candidate countries will become members as of 2004 and that Bulgaria and Romania will join in 2007. Turkey is not considered in this study, except insofar that it is assumed that the EU budget will continue to include
The period
45
5.1A
All comparisons will be benchmarked against a
A less dramatic, but also important, consideration is that the present Financial Perspective has tailored the expenditure for EU 15 in such a way as to make it possible to accommodate the enlargement (by 6 countries). Had enlargement not been an option in the 1999 negotiations, it is highly likely that the budgetary costs for covering the present membership would have been considerably higher than is now the case.
Nevertheless, the
5.1.1 The characteristics of the benchmark scenario
The benchmark scenario is presented in appendix table 2. Overall, it is characterized by strong budget discipline, basically freezing the expenditure levels for EU 15 at the 2006 level, which is practically the same as the level in 2000. Since GNP is assumed to increase at a steady rate (2.5 % annually for the present EU 15 members, 4 % annually for new member states, measured in 1999 prices) this implies that the share of the
46
over the
There are some fundamental assumptions, which will influence the comparison with all other scenarios.
The cost for agricultural policy after 2006 has been estimated under the assumption that the present system for CAP will remain in force but that the total agricultural expenditure will remain at the level of 2006.
For structural operations it has also been assumed in the benchmark scenario that expenditure and distribution on member states will be frozen at the level of 2006 for all EU 15 countries. The same assumption has been made for Internal policy and
Administrative expenditure. As far External expenditure, which includes
5.1.2 The relation between payments and expenditure
The issue of the ratio between the level of payments and the level of commitments has already been mentioned above (se section 3.1). The present study concentrates on the level of payments, since that is the parameter, which determines contributions, net positions and so on. For EU 15 the difference between commitments and payments is normally trivial over the long run, whereas it will have a significant impact in the new member states. As far as EU 15 is concerned we will therefore limit ourselves to noting that the level of payments has been calculated with the help of the overall ratio of payments to commitments in the Financial Perspective. When determining that ratio agriculture, payments towards reserves and administrative expenditure have been excluded since it is assumed that for those categories commitments and payments are entirely synonymous.
In contrast to EU 15 the difference between the level of payments and the level of commitments becomes very important for the new member states. We can regard commitments for direct income support to agriculture as identical to payments but for all other categories of expenditure there will be a considerable lag in payments in relation to the commitments made, mainly due to
47
lacking absorptive capacity in the new member states and the time needed to start new programs. This has to do on the one hand with the deficient institutional structure in the recipient countries and on the other with the complicated planning and approval procedure for many EU programs. This has been amply demonstrated by the difficulties the candidate countries are experiencing in benefiting from the
The CFF contains figure for both commitments and payments for the years
5.2A Least Resistance scenario
5.2.1 Assumptions
We have labeled the first enlargement scenario to be explored “the Least Resistance scenario.” Like all enlargement scenarios it is based on the CFF for the period
The assumptions for structural operations are a bit more involved. Obviously in a “Least Resistance” scenario (which might also be termed “Business as usual”) we would start by assuming that there would be no reform of the present system. But if structural funds in an enlarged union were allocated following the same rules as those in force by 2006, many of the present member states would lose large parts of their structural support. As a matter
22 This underutilization led to a giant surplus on the EU annual budget for 2001 (around 15 %), which will be repaid to the contributors.
48
of fact, the total costs of structural operations in the enlarged EU would become lower than at present because many EU 15 countries would no longer be eligible for certain funds while at the same time those funds could not be fully allocated to new members. This is because the majority of the new member states would reach the ceiling of 4 % of GDP that is imposed as a maximum for structural funds, well before the end of the period under consideration. In order to avoid those peculiar consequences we have assumed in the Least Resistance Scenario that structural support to the countries of EU 15 will be frozen at the levels reached by 2006. This means that none of the present EU 15 member states would lose structural or cohesion fund support as a consequence of enlargement. This assumption is certainly somewhat extreme and will be relaxed in one of the reform scenarios in chapter 6.
Expenditure on internal policy has also been frozen at the 2006 level. For new member states the figures of CFF have been used and distributed in relation to their GDP. The same has been done for administrative expenditure with the important difference that all additional administrative expenditure has been allocated to EU 15, that is to say mainly to Belgium and Luxembourg.
In this scenario the same assumptions have been made as in the benchmark scenario with respect to
For the period 2004 to 2006 in the Least Resistance Scenario, we have assumed that the whole difference between funds earmarked for enlargement in the Financial Perspective and the expenditure according to the CFF will be used for budgetary compensations to new member states as well as for unforeseen expenditure. The Commission has proposed that compensation should be paid to new member states in relation to changes in their financial net position before and after accession.
5.2.2 Results of the Least Resistance Scenario
The results are presented in table 6 in the form of enlargement costs as shares of GNP. Absolute amounts are shown in appendix table 3.
As we can see the enlargement will have a cost impact corresponding to 0.03 % of the GNP of the expanded EU in 2004, rising to 0.23 % in 2013. For reasons that will be further explained in forthcoming sections, the impact is marginally lower on EU 15
49
and on present net payers. Since new member states do not pay anything towards the EU budget before their accession, the impact will be equal to their total payments as a share of GNP.
The estimated total payments as a share of GNP for all countries are shown in table 9. It is clear that in no way is the 1.27 % ceiling for own resources threatened by a development such as the one assumed in this scenario.
Table 6. Enlargement costs in a Least Resistance Scenario.
Percentage shares of GNP/GDP
2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 | |
Berlin net payers (D, NL, A, SE) | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.23 |
Net payers without rebate (DK, F, I, Fin) | 0.02 | 0.08 | 0.16 | 0.20 | 0.22 |
Sum | 0.02 | 0.08 | 0.16 | 0.20 | 0.22 |
UK | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.22 |
All net payers | 0.02 | 0.09 | 0.16 | 0.20 | 0.22 |
Cohesion countries (Gr, Irl, E, P) | 0.02 | 0.08 | 0.16 | 0.20 | 0.22 |
EU adm countries (B, Lx) | 0.02 | 0.08 | 0.16 | 0.20 | 0.22 |
EU 15 total | 0.02 | 0.08 | 0.16 | 0.20 | 0.22 |
Baltic countries (EE, L, Lit) | 1.11 | 1.13 | 1.20 | 1.19 | 1.15 |
Visegrad countries (PI, H, CZ, Sl) | 1.11 | 1.13 | 1.20 | 1.19 | 1.15 |
Slovenia | 1.11 | 1.13 | 1.20 | 1.19 | 1.15 |
Island states (C, M) | 1.11 | 1.13 | 1.20 | 1.19 | 1.15 |
Bulgaria and Romania | 0.00 | 0.00 | 1.20 | 1.19 | 1.15 |
New MS total | 1.11 | 1.13 | 1.20 | 1.19 | 1.15 |
EU enlarged | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.23 |
Source: Own estimates. |
5.2.3The importance of growth
In all scenarios it has been assumed that the GNP of all EU 15 countries will grow by 2.5 % annually (in volume terms) after 2003 and that the GNP of all new member states will grow by 4 % annually, thus taking some step towards convergence. Some sort of standard assumption is obviously necessary since it would be a futile task to try to make individual growth forecasts for a large
50
number of countries over this long period.23 The assumptions that have been made lie in all likelihood around the average capacity growth of the member countries. The various scenarios are all based on an assumed growth rate of budgetary expenditure that falls well below the one assumed for the GNP. The payments to the budget, therefore, will by necessity fall over time when expressed as a share of GNP.
In order to show the importance of the growth assumptions, a variation of the Least Resistance Scenario was carried out in which growth rates were lowered to 1.5 % annually for EU 15. The growth rate for new member states was maintained at 4 % annually.
We note that the change of growth assumptions has a significant impact on the enlargement costs expressed as a share of the GNP and mainly towards the end of the period studied. In 2013, for example, the enlargement costs would amount to 0.30 % of the GNP of the enlarged Union with the lower growth assumption against 0.23 % with the standard assumption.
It must be stressed that these estimates must be considered mainly as a mechanical sensitivity analysis. It is difficult to envisage why and how the lower
Table 7. Enlargement costs in the Least Resistance Scenario with different growth assumptions.
Percentage share of GNP of the enlarged EU
2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 | |
Standard growth | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.23 |
Slower growth | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.18 | 0.25 | 0.30 |
Source: Own estimates (Least Resistance Scenario).
23 Dresdner Bank, 2001, makes courageous assumptions of growth rates in the individual candidate countries for the period
51
5.2.4 The importance of the time profile of accession
The importance of the timing of the accession will be illustrated in another variation on the Least Resistance Scenario. Without basing ourselves on any deeper political analysis we will assume that certain changes in the present roadmap to enlargement will appear. We will thereby assume that there will be no enlargement in 2004, that the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Slovenia and Malta will join in 2005, that the accession of Cyprus, Poland, Latvia, Lithuania and Slovakia will be delayed until 2007 and that Bulgaria and Romania will join only in 2009.24 The impact on costs of such a time profile for accession is contrasted with the one of the original Least Resistance Scenario in table 8.
What happens if enlargement gets delayed and/or split up in several country groups is obviously that the payments of the enlargement costs will be postponed. In the variation presented in table 8, the total cumulative budgetary costs of enlargement would become about 25 % lower over the period
Even if such a cost reduction might have some attraction from a budgetary point of view, it must be remembered that there would be severe political and maybe social costs of a delayed enlargement in which some countries would become members before others. This scenario variation must only be regarded as a sensitivity analysis of the calculations presented in our study. This being said, a ratcheting of enlargement could have a significant budgetary impact. This was seen already in table 2 where the actual EU budget costs are hovering just above and considerably below 1 % of GNP and might jump to 1.11 % the first year of accession, if budgetary costs were to reach the levels included in the Financial Perspective and the CFF respectively.
24 As already stated there is no deeper political analysis behind this assumed pattern of accession but neither is it entirely without foundation, as the reflecting reader will understand. This might happen.
52
Table 8. Enlargement costs in the Least Resistance Scenario with different time profiles for accession.
Percentage share of GNP
2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 | |
Standard Time Profile | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.23 |
Alternative Time Profile | 0.01 | 0.03 | 0.08 | 0.17 | 0.20 |
Source: Own estimates (Least Resistance Scenario)
Note: Standard time profile: 10 countries accede in 2004, 2 countries in 2007. Alternative time profile: 5 countries accede in 2005, 5 countries in 2007 and 2 countries in 2009 (see text for further explanation). The amounts for
5.2.5 Budgetary compensation to new member states
Upon membership every country also becomes part of the socalled Own Resources System.25 One of the cornerstones of the system was supposed to be equity among the member states. In other words all members should contribute to an equal degree to the financing of the budget for the Union. All redistribution of financial resources should be made on the expenditure side.
The above has led to the apprehension that new member states might be in a worse financial position after joining the EU than before since they will have to pay their full contribution to the EU budget from the very outset of their membership. Their net position will depend on the amounts of expenditure allocated to them and on their capacity to absorb or make use of available funds, particularly at the beginning of their membership, which may be weak. The Commission has proposed that budgetary compensations be paid to new members in order to avoid that that accession would have a negative impact on their budgetary position. For technical reasons such compensation must be given in the form of lump sum payments rather than as rebates on the payments.26
At all previous enlargements a financial compensation has been given to the new members, with various motivations. At the most recent enlargement Austria, Finland and Sweden were granted
25See EC, 1998, for a detailed description and assessment of the system.
26A rebate would require an amendment of the Own Resources Decision, theoretically possible but in real life absolutely out of question.
53
1998.27 This is approximately equal to the presently suggested amounts of 0.8 billions annually for 3 years (EC 30.1.2002, ref 9). Our estimates show that such an amount would correspond to a cost increase of approximately 0.01 % of GNP per year over the three years. In the context of
5.2.6Summary of the impact on costs of enlargement without policy reforms
It might be useful at this particular juncture to make a comparison of the total enlargement costs between the Financial Perspective, the Benchmark Scenario and the least Resistance Scenario and the variations that we have made. The results are shown in table 9. When comparing with the Financial Perspective we must remember that the assumed time profile for enlargement in the FP differed from the one now envisaged and also that the GNP- numbers have been revised since the FP was drawn up in 1999. We note in particular the following:
1The estimates of the enlargement costs 2004– 2006 are significantly lower in the Least Resistance Scenario than in the Financial Perspective in spite of the fact that they cover 10 countries instead of 6. The estimates of the Least Resistance Scenario are based on the CFF.
2When related to the GNP of the enlarged EU the total payments, including the costs of enlargement, appear considerably lower, both for the present EU 15 and for the enlarged Union as a whole, than when related to the GNP of EU 15 only. (The latter was the case in tables 1 and 2 above.)
The last point may seem
27 See EC, 1999, p. 8, footnote3.
54
the end of the period studied. This could lead the casual observer to believe that the so called Own Resources Ceiling of 1.27 % of GNP might be threatened by the enlargement, particularly if even more pessimistic assumptions about the costs than the one we have used are made.28
The reason why we are sometimes misled is that we tend to neglect the increase in the GNP of the Union brought about by the new membership as well as the contributions to the EU budget coming from those countries. It is true that those increases are relatively small but, as we will demonstrate later, they nevertheless have a significant effect on the burden sharing within the Union.29 Table 9 shows us that enlargement costs would reach no higher than 0.23 % by the end of the period when related to the GNP of all countries that will have to share the financial burden.
Concerning total payments to the EU budget, after enlargement, the Low Growth Scenario shows the highest costs in relation to GNP but even those numbers are a far cry away from the Own Resource Ceiling of 1.27 % of GNP.
28The Own Resources Decision stipulates that the EU may never charge more than 1.27 % of the GNP of the Union as
29See section 7.3 below.
55
Table 9. Enlargement costs and total payments after enlargement in various scenarios.
Percentage shares of the GNP of the enlarged EU
2002 2004 2006 2007 2010 2013
1 Enlargement costs
In the Financial Perspective | 0.01 | 0.06 | 0.12 | |||
Estimates in the Least Resistance | ||||||
Scenario | ||||||
Standard assumptions | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.23 | |
Low Growth | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.18 | 0.25 | 0.30 | |
Alternative Time Profile | 0.01 | 0.03 | 0.08 | 0.17 | 0.20 |
2 Total payments to the EU budget
In the Financial Perspective | 1.14 | 1.11 | 1.09 | |||
Estimates in the Least Resistance | ||||||
Scenario | ||||||
Standard assumptions | 1.10 | 1.03 | 1.05 | 1.12 | 1.09 | 1.04 |
Low Growth | 1.10 | 1.03 | 1.05 | 1.13 | 1.13 | 1.11 |
Alternative Time Profile | 1.10 | 1.00 | 0.98 | 1.03 | 1.05 | 1.02 |
Source: The Financial Perspective 2000 2006 (EC, 1999). Own estimates.
Note: See text for explanations of low growth and alternative time profile assumptions.
56
6Enlargement costs in reform scenarios
6.1Cutting costs through policy reforms
This section will analyze the budgetary impact of a couple of scenarios where the development is assumed to take directions other than those in the “Least Resistance Scenario.” Possible reforms of the common agricultural policy and the structural policy are the most important alternatives. It is important to understand, however, that it is not the aim of the present study to undertake any
6.1.1 A less expensive agricultural policy
The common agricultural policy (CAP) covers around 46 % of the total EU budget. Historically, CAP was designed with a food security aim but has developed into a mechanism for supporting agricultural prices, thereby securing the income levels of the farmers. Protectionist measures and market interventions leading to a price level more or less constantly above world market prices led to overproduction and the notorious “mountains” or “lakes” of various agricultural produce emerged. The European consumers, at the same time, were prevented from enjoying the lower food prices
57
through the protectionist measures. This became an untenable situation and in 1992 a reform was carried out, bringing the EU market intervention prices somewhat closer to, but still above, the world market prices. Since this inevitably meant falling income for European farmers, a compensatory system of direct support was introduced with its own rules and stipulations, often connected with an undertaking to lay land fallow.30 With time, environmental requirements and a special rural development support were introduced.
It is difficult today to find anyone defending the CAP except those directly benefiting financially or politically from the system. In addition it contains certain features that are not compatible with the WTO rules. The Agenda 2000 negotiations offered an unprecedented possibility to assess the system and agree on the necessary reforms in view of the impending enlargement. However, the agreements of Berlin were not even
The proposed payment of direct income support to farmers in new candidate countries is the most critical issue. In the financial perspective
30The technique to lower intervention prices and increase direct payments is often referred to as shifting the costs from the consumer to the taxpayer, which should have some interesting domestic income distribution effects.
31For an excellent analysis of what really happened in Berlin see Schwaag Serger, 2001, which also is an interesting case study of
58
Term Review (EC, 2002, ref 13) and, in reality, most of the members of EU 15 have tacitly agreed that nowadays the direct payments are rather a way of generally propping up the agricultural sector. The issue is to what extent and for how long that policy is sustainable.
The CFF foresees a gradual phasing in of direct support payments to the new member states in such a way that they would receive direct support payments to a level of 25 % in 2004, 30 % in 2005 and 35 % in 2006 of the present system. Making a remarkable departure from the rule not to discuss the development after 2006, the CFF goes on to propose that by 2013 the new member states would reach 100 % of “the support level then applicable.” (EC, 30.1.2002, ref 9, and EC, 30.1.2002, ref 10.)
The CFF has been received with a mixture of pain and indignation by the candidate countries, which feel that the proposal would brand them as
Chances of a thorough reform32 of the agricultural policy would seem to be remote. Schwaag Serger, 2000, analyzes in a convincing way why this is so. France, in particular, plays a key role. Not only is France the major net beneficiary of CAP but the policy also seems to have a solid ideological foundation and be regarded as a major pillar of the European cooperation. (op. cit. page 70 et passim). Quaisser and Hall, 2002, believe that “France might be willing to promote a CAP reform if offered a
32 For the sake of simplicity we are only discussing a reduction of the direct income support payments. There are also a number of other measures for reforming the CAP that would be required, for instance, with respect to production quotas. Many also favor an increased emphasis on rural development measures, which have a strong environmental component.
59
In order to illustrate the budgetary impact of a possible reform of direct support payments we have estimated a scenario in which payments will be reduced to 85 % of their present level by 2013, through continuous phasing out of payments to the present EU 15. We assume this phasing out to start after 2006. It would correspond to an annual decrease of 3.14 %. We retain the proposal of the Commission of phasing in direct support payments in such a way that the new member states would receive 100 % of the possible support in 2013. That level, however, would now be 20 % lower than what the present system would give. In that way all member countries (with a temporary exception of Bulgaria and Romania) would receive equal treatment by that year.
Since we are addressing here one of the biggest budgetary items of the Union, even relatively modest savings, such as 15 % over a
Table 10. Impact of a reduction of agricultural expenditure on enlargement costs.
Percentage share of GNP of the enlarged union
Net cost of enlargement: | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 |
Without agricultural reform | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.23 |
With 3.14 % annual reduction of direct | 0.16 | 0.18 | 0.18 |
support costs 2007 2013 | |||
Source: Own estimates.
Note: In this table we use the term ”net cost of enlargement” since the reduction of costs would come from a cut in the agricultural expenditure allocated to EU 15 whereas the enlargement costs proper would be the same as in the standard alternative.
This policy alternative would seem very attractive from a budgetary point of view but its possibilities of being implemented are very much in doubt. Schwaag Serger, 2001, gives a full review of the various proposals made before Berlin and the negotiation games. At one point an annual degressivity of direct support payments of 3 % was a serious possibility but disappeared in the final cutting of the deal. In a very simplified way of looking at matters, countries
60
that are net payers to the EU budget would be in favor of partial renationalization of the agricultural policy and/or degressivity of direct support payments. But the issue is complicated, among other things by the relative importance of the agricultural sector and the share of the agricultural budget, which is allocated back to the member countries. France receives around 22 % of the EU budget of EU 15 and Germany around 14 %. The relation between the
In July 2002, the Commission presented its
Since the proposal in the
33 France at one point of time accepted the degressivity principle during the Agenda 2000 negotiating but insisted that the savings would be used for rual development policy instead. (Schwaag Serger, 2001, page 115 et passim.) Quaisser and Hall, 2002, argue that the agricultural net position of France may suffer sufficiently from the access of new member states into the system that it might be willing to promote a CAP reform (op. cit. p.48). We cannot see this.
61
6.1.2 Structural policy: same rules for all?
The heading Structural Operation covers around 33 % of total EU 15 expenditure in the Financial Perspective
The functioning and impact of the structural policy of the EU has been the object of a number of evaluations and assessments. The latest assessment from the side of the Commission is EC 30.1. 2002, ref 11, which, among other things, presents the proposed criteria for structural support to the new member states during the years
Even if a reform of the structural policy of the Union would be due under all circumstances, it is clear that the enlargement of the Union will fundamentally impact the regional cohesion within the Union. The accession of
In addition to the issues raised by the enlargement there are many other question marks surrounding the regional and cohesion policy of the EU. A
34 The study contains an extensive summary in English.
62
but rather in terms of other or subsidiary goals such as facilitating the integration process, strengthening sectoral polices and the institutional development. Broadly speaking this is because the structural and cohesion funds have functioned as a pool of money that could be deployed in order to remove political obstacles on the road to integration. Expressed in a cruder fashion: to buy out countries that otherwise would refuse to participate in the one or the other reform process.
Leading politicians have raised the question whether the future regional and cohesion policy should not be exclusively directed towards the poorest member states, in other words the present candidate countries. A negotiated share of the EU budget should be set aside for this purpose and distributed following certain criteria to the poorest member states. Those criteria could be either of a national or a regional nature and the use of funds could be controlled either at the national or the Union level.
Those proposals unfortunately meet with strong objections since there are a number of the present EU 15 member states that happily enjoy the benefits of the present regional policy. Apart from the present
Another problem with a reform along such lines is that the present regional policy is the only visible and strong link between regions in the member countries and the administration in Brussels.37 The availability of EU support for local projects has without doubt contributed significantly towards creating a positive grass root attitude towards the Union and the European
35The Netherlands is one of the very few countries which do not benefit from the regional development policy of the Union. In jest (?) a representative of the Dutch Government suggested to the author that a
36Informal communication to the author from the Ministry of Finance in one of the countries concerned.
37This is convincingly demonstrated in the report from the Cohesion Forum in Brussels, May 2001, attended by 1 800 delegates from national and regional authorities and interest groups. (See EC, 30.1.2002, ref 11) for further reference.
63
cooperation in contrast to the archetypal prejudice against the “bureaucracy in Brussels.” It is obviously dangerous to rely on anecdotal evidence but when traveling through the countryside of any member country an observer is likely to be impressed by the number of small signs with the European emblem and some variation of the text “supported by the EU.”
Another way of approaching reform of the structural and cohesion policy would be to advocate “same rules for all” after the accession of new member states. A negotiated proportion of the EU budget should be set aside for regional and structural policy. All member states would be eligible and the distribution should follow the same criteria as at present (possibly in a somewhat simplified fashion). Attractive – and fair – as this idea may seem the
In this study we have assumed that the
As we can see from the table the principle of
Another issue relating to structural operations policy concerns the
64
the resistance from net payers is strong and unanimous on this point. There is however another good reason not to relax this limitation: without the capping the net positions of the new member states would reach unrealistic values of 8 to 10 % for the Baltic countries and much higher for Bulgaria and Romania. Three of the four Visegrad countries would still not reach the 4 % ceiling and only Poland would attain a net position in 2013 of between 4 and 5 %, which might or might not be considered as manageable. Already there are justified concerns about the absorptive capacity of the new member states, that is to say their ability to utilize the funds put at their disposal from the Union budget. Partly this is due to the extremely complicated planning and programming procedure for utilizing structural support allocations but mainly the requirements of
Table 11. Impact of different alternatives for structural operations policy on enlargement costs.
Percentage share of GNP/GDP
Net cost of enlargement | 2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 |
With full compensation to EU 15 | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.23 |
With the same rules for all | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.04 | 0.08 | 0.11 |
Same rule for all but no 4 % cap on | |||||
structural funds | 0.04 | 0.11 | 0.17 | 0.20 | 0.20 |
Source: Own estimates.
Note: In this table we use the term ”net cost of enlargement” since the reduction of costs would come from a reduction of structural operations expenditure allocated to EU 15 whereas the enlargement costs proper would be the same as in the standard alternative.
65
Our
6.2Summary of the cost estimates
6.2.1 A recap of our scenarios
It is now high time to sum up the various cost estimates described in the sections above and in chapter 5. Table 12 summarizes the impact of the enlargement expressed as percentages of GNP or GDP of the enlarged Union. In the Least Resistance Scenario, which includes no CAP reform and no reduction of structural support to EU 15, the costs would go from 0.03 % of GNP/GDP of the enlarged Union in 2004 to 0.23 % in 2013. We see also that either of the two reform alternatives, a modest reduction of direct support payments or application of the same rules for structural funds for all member countries, would reduce those costs in a very significant manner. Even if we take away the 4 % cap on structural funds, total costs would be somewhat lower than in the Least Resistance Scenario.
A phasing out of direct support payments obviously would create a huge potential for budgetary savings. Here, as in other contexts, a lot of caution is required: we have not at all gone into the problems of what kind of national policies that might be required or permitted in order to support the agricultural sector or backward regions. A heavy restructuring of the agricultural sector in Europe would have social costs, which must be covered by
38 As quoted in EC, 30.1.2002, ref. 11. What was agreed was, however, the absolute amount of support, not the share of GNP. This share as such can therefore not be considered part of the acquis. The Commission quotes, nevertheless, studies by independent research institutes claiming that 0.50 – 0.65 % of GDP should be set aside for community structural and cohesion policy. Maybe, but it is difficult to reconcile such claims with the absorptive capacity of the receiving countries. The formulation and execution of policy would have to be fully redefined in order to put even larger funds than at present to use.
66
national policy measures. It is likely, nevertheless, that such measures could be made more efficient than the present system.
As mentioned in the text above, we have seen that budgetary compensations to new member states for a couple of years would have a very small impact on total enlargement costs. A delay in the enlargement process, such as the one outlined in section 5.4.4 above would obviously shift the costs forward in time. Table 12 shows us that, in the example we have used, enlargement costs would go from 0.01 % of GNP of the enlarged Union in 2004 to 0.20 % in 2013. Whereas this might bring about some
Table 12. Summary of enlargement costs in different scenarios.
Percentage shares of GNP/GDP
2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 | |
Least Resistance | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 0.21 | 0.23 |
Degressivity of direct support | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.16 | 0.18 | 0.18 |
Same rules for all in structural | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.04 | 0.08 | 0.11 |
operations | |||||
Same rules but no cap on | 0.04 | 0.11 | 0.17 | 0.20 | 0.20 |
structural operation | |||||
Low growth in EU 15 | 0.03 | 0.09 | 0.18 | 0.25 | 0.30 |
Delayed and |
0.01 | 0.03 | 0.08 | 0.17 | 0.20 |
enlargement |
Source: Own estimates.
Another observation that can be made from table 12 is that a slowdown in growth in the EU 15 area after 2006 would have a significant effect on costs when expressed as a share of GNP/GDP. We are, however, in doubt as to whether those growth assumptions would be consistent with the assumptions of expenditure development. A growth rate of 1.5 % annually would probably be well below capacity growth in EU 15 and hence would indicate a permanent state of underutilization of resources, which would probably not be compatible with implementing the ambitious project of integrating 12 new member states. It is meaningless to speculate on the kind of policy actions that might become necessary in such a situation – this would obviously also depend on the underlying causes of the slow growth. The indicated scenario
67
should be seen only as a mechanical sensitivity analysis. Nevertheless, there is one important lesson to be learned: accommodation of the costs related to enlargement will require a
Table 13 summarizes the results expressed as total payments of various country groups in some of the key scenarios. We note that even in the lax Least Resistance scenario the payment quotas for the different country groups would have maximum value of between 0.82 % (UK) and 1.20 % of GNP/GDP (new member states). This corresponds to a value of slightly above 1.10 % of GNP/GDP of the enlarged union (not shown in the table).
Table 13. Total payments to the EU budget in different enlargement scenarios.
Percentage shares of GNP/GDP
2002 | 2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 | |
Least Resistance scenario | ||||||
Net payers (except UK) | 1.16 | 1.07 | 1.10 | 1.17 | 1.14 | 1.10 |
UK | 0.79 | 0.75 | 0.75 | 0.82 | 0.74 | 0.70 |
EU 15 total | 1.10 | 1.02 | 1.03 | 1.11 | 1.08 | 1.04 |
New member states | 0.00 | 1.11 | 1.13 | 1.20 | 1.19 | 1.15 |
Same rules for all in | ||||||
structural operations | ||||||
Net payers (except UK) | 1.16 | 1.07 | 1.10 | 1.04 | 1.01 | 0.97 |
UK | 0.79 | 0.75 | 0.75 | 0.69 | 0.69 | 0.65 |
EU 15 total | 1.10 | 1.02 | 1.04 | 0.98 | 0.96 | 0.92 |
New member states | 0.00 | 1.11 | 1.13 | 1.08 | 1.05 | 1.01 |
Low growth in EU 15 | ||||||
Net payers (except UK) | 1.16 | 1.07 | 1.10 | 1.18 | 1.19 | 1.17 |
UK | 0.79 | 0.75 | 0.75 | 0.82 | 0.77 | 0.75 |
EU 15 total | 1.10 | 1.04 | 1.04 | 1.12 | 1.12 | 1.11 |
New member states | 0.00 | 1.13 | 1.13 | 1.22 | 1.24 | 1.22 |
Source: Own estimates.
But we also see that there are great disparities between the country groups. The very low share of the UK stands out. On the other hand the shares of the new member states are higher than for the net payers. Although this is not shown in the table the same would be true for the cohesion countries of the present EU 15. The reason behind this anomaly is that the payment share of EU 15 is
68
significantly reduced by the UK rebate and the discount on payments granted four other countries.
A fuller presentation of the scenario results is given in Appendix 2, tables
6.2.2 What other studies say
A number of studies of the costs of enlargement have been published since the beginning of the 1990’s. It is, however, not so easy to compare the results of those studies with each other or with our own results since methods and assumptions vary considerably. The time profile of the accession has generally been identical with the one foreseen in the Financial Perspective, that is to say with 6 countries acceding in 2002 and with a supplementary assumption of 4 or 6 countries acceding in 2007. We have seen in section 5.2.4 above and in table 9 that the time profile for accession can have a very significant impact on the distribution of costs over time. Since we now assume a big bang enlargement with 10 countries by 2004 most earlier estimates show higher costs than our study for the period
A recent study by Quaisser and Hall, 2002, takes into account both the likely change in time profile for access as well as the proposed Common Financial Framework for the period
As already pointed out in Karlsson, 2001, econometric studies of the enlargement costs generally tend to indicate higher costs than the accounting approach we are using for our estimates. The reason for this seems to be that those studies are based on implicit or explicit relations between the development of expenditure and economic structure or voting behavior in the European Council.41
39For reviews and summaries of earlier studies of enlargement costs see mainly Karlsson, 2002, Baldwin et al., 1997, Stankovsky et al., 1998 and Quaisser et al., 2000.
40Quaisser and Hall, 2002, p. 32 et passim.
41See for instance Baldwin et al., 1997.
69
Whereas this is an excellent way of analyzing and explaining what has happened so far, the forecasting ability of such methods is of course less certain. We have followed another approach and taken as a given starting point that the Financial Perspective agreed on in Berlin indicates a permanent (or at least
This assumption may of course turn out to be wrong. Quaisser and Hall, 2002, show that after enlargement countries which contribute around 80 % of the budget would have only around 60 % of the votes in the Council after the Nice agreements. Net recipients, contributing 20 % to the budget, would have almost 40 % of the votes. The authors assess the risks for a future “explosion in costs”42 as rather high. This assessment is based mainly on an assumption of an accelerating growth in the new member states which would raise the 4 % cap for structural funds in absolute amounts plus an assumption that new member states would be able to make full use of all structural funds available to them from the very beginning. We are not fully convinced of this, given what we know about the absorptive capacity of the candidate countries. Normally accelerating growth would also mean less need for support to backward regions.
6.3Is there a worse scenario?
The estimates above and tables 12 and 13 have probably left the impression that the enlargement costs, also in the perspective of the period up to 2013, are within the limits that member countries must have reckoned with when the enlargement project started to take form. Although we reject the 1.27 % ceiling as a policy parameter it is an agreed maximum, which will hardly be threatened, even in the more pessimistic alternatives. But what would a real “worst case” scenario look like? We recall that even in the Least Resistance Scenario above we have included full direct support payments to agriculture in new member states after a phasing in period suggested by the Commission. We have not assumed any reform of the present system. Furthermore, we have assumed that all EU 15 countries would receive full compensation
42 Quaisser and Hall, 2002, p. 35.
70
for the losses of structural support funds that they would suffer if a
Without losing all internal consistency it might be possible to tighten the screws one or more additional turns. The opposition to the phasing in proposal from the candidate countries is very strong. We could therefore envisage a solution where full direct support was paid as early as of 2007. In other scenarios we have not included any increase in administrative costs or internal policy after 2006, knowing well that those are the favorite areas of budget negotiators.43 We could therefore add an increase in those items, perhaps at the same rate as the one foreseen for the period 2000– 2006 in the Financial Perspective. We further assume a 5 % increase in the policy area “External Expenditure”.
Of all those assumptions only the increase in direct support payments to new member states from 2007 onwards has a significant effect on total costs. Since Bulgaria and Romania would be entitled to very high support payments in an
It would of course be possible to relax simultaneously further constraints imposed on the previous calculations, for example by not using the 4 % cap on structural expenditure and assuming a lower growth rate in EU 15 and by assuming falling instead of rising world market prices for agricultural products. We fear that our accounting approach to the issue of enlargement costs would break down if new assumptions along those lines were introduced. Such an analysis would no doubt require a dynamic econometric analysis of a general equilibrium character.
43 Sometimes unwisely, as we will argue below, since some of the net payers enjoy a substantial net inflow of funds from the policy area ”internal policy.” But we must refer to the timeless example of the bicycle shed and the nuclear reactor in Parkinson’s Law (Parkinson, 1958) corroborating the thesis that ”the time spent on any item of the agenda will be in inverse proportion in the sum involved” (op.cit., p.63).
71
It is, of course, possible that there could be new initiatives in an enlarged union to increase rather than to restrict the community activities and the budget. Cost intensive common policy actions in the fields of for example energy and environment but possibly also in areas such as crime prevention, defense and general security and maybe, in a more positive vein, in information infrastructure, education or advanced research are fully possible. This might lead to a considerable expansion of the EU budget but would then be the result of explicit policy decisions, mostly taken in consensus. As such they would fall outside the scope of this study which focuses on issues that are either already included in the existing system or will appear in the future as a consequence thereof.
72
Part 2. Equity in a large union
7 Sharing the financial burden
7.1The issue of budgetary imbalances
In table 3 we have already shown how the payments for the EU- budget will be distributed, in total and for the enlargement in particular, between various country groups. We have stressed that the basic idea of equity in burden sharing has become severely distorted by the UK rebate and the discount relating to Germany, Sweden, the Netherlands and Austria but also because of variations in the
When assessing the relative financial plights of the member countries there is another fundamental aspect to take into account, namely the budgetary balance or, as we will call it in this study, the (budgetary) net position. Except for the external expenditure the whole EU budget is spent within the Union, that is to say allocated to the individual member countries. The biggest policy areas, agricultural policy and structural operations, have their own set of rules for distributing the funds. There are special rules also for the category Internal policy. Even the administrative expenditure benefits the member countries and particularly the countries where the central administration is located, that is to say Belgium and Luxembourg.44
It is possible to calculate the difference between payments and allocated expenditure for each member country, in order to
44 At the time of writing, EU institutions are located to all EU 15 countries except Sweden and Finland. All countries have, however, a
73
determine a budget balance or net position. Without supplementing assumptions the sum of those net positions would not be equal to 0 since around 10 % of the budget is spent as external expenditure (of which preaccession aid is one important part).
The net position is an analytically doubtful concept of very little macroeconomic relevance. It is also difficult to calculate since parts of the expenditure are not allocated via public sector budgets but go directly to institutions, organizations, enterprises or individuals in the form of research grants, consultancy fees, procurement payments and so on. A large part of the funds allocated back to the member countries requires national
In the past, the European Commission has argued forcefully that the net position cannot be a correct measure of the economic, social and welfare benefits gained from a EU membership (EC, 1998, ch. 2 et passim). We share this opinion fully. At the same time, we have to accept that, unfortunately, the net position has become an official concept in the Union. At the meeting of the European Council in Fontainebleau in 1984 all countries with significant budgetary imbalances “in relation to their relative level of prosperity” were granted a possibility of achieving an adjustment. This was, however, mainly an alibi action for granting the UK its considerable rebate on its payments. No other country has so far obtained a similar advantage.46
It is possible to define the net position in several different ways. The only official definition available is, however, the one used for determining the UK rebate. For the purposes of this study we will therefore use the
45We will argue in section 8.2 that it might even be against the interest of a net payer to try to increase its share of the allocated expenditure.
46Except that Germany, as the largest net payer, had a small rebate on its share of financing the UK rebate, which may have been the precedent for the decision in Berlin 1999 to grant 4 countries a similar, but larger, discount.
74
for each country custom duties are taken into account only in relation to its share of VAT- and
It is interesting to note that in connection with the enlargement negotiations the Commission seems to have abandoned, at least temporarily, its objections to the use of net positions as a political concept and its earlier insistence on using the UK rebate definition. The Commission has proposed that budgetary compensations should be paid to new member countries if their net position would be less advantageous after than before accession and that this be defined as the cash difference between payments and funds received.48
After this somewhat longwinded introduction we will start by giving a picture of the burden sharing among the present EU 15 member states. Thereafter we will analyze how the various enlargement scenarios, elaborated in previous chapters, will affect the distribution of the financial burden.
7.2Burden sharing in EU 15
The actual situation in 2000 is set out in table 14. The table shows clearly the dominating position of Germany as a contributor and as a net payer. We can also see that four countries, Germany, France, Italy and the UK pay almost 70 % of the EU budget, a share that will change only marginally when the Union is enlarged. The same countries receive together somewhat more than 50 % of the allocated expenditure. Nine out of the fifteen members are net payers. Of the net receivers, Spain receives most funds in absolute numbers, followed by Greece.
The strong positive net positions of Belgium and Luxembourg are the results of the allocation of the administrative costs of the EU. They constitute, nevertheless, real positive contributions to the economies of those two countries.49
47The author feels a certain need to apologize for these technicalities. But, to quote the American columnist Dave Barry; ”I am not making this up!”
48In other words the accounting definition otherwise advocated by large net payers such as the Netherlands and Sweden. Appendix 1 shows why.
49The multiplier effects on the domestic economy are probably smaller in Luxembourg than i Belgium because of a higher import leakage.
75
To understand the sharing of the financial burden we have to look at the net position in relation to the GNP and, maybe, in relation to the population of the country. Three net payers stand out: Germany, the Netherlands and Sweden with negative shares of
We should remember that the actual size of the net position also depends on the definition that is used. Appendix 1 shows that with alternative definitions the net positions cold be very different, particularly for the Netherlands (more negative) and for Belgium and Luxembourg (much more positive).
For the future, and in particular in the perspective of the enlargement of the union, present members cannot expect any increase in allocated expenditure from the EU budget. Since at the same time total costs and thereby payments will increase at least to some extent, the net positions of present members will deteriorate to a varying degree. Countries like Denmark, France, Italy, Austria and maybe Finland will find themselves in the position of significant net payers. (France and Austria are already net payers but their importance as such will increase.) The traditional main net payers Germany, the Netherlands and Sweden will see their share of the financial burden further increase. At the same time present net receivers risk seeing the financial inflows shrink, in particular if there would be reforms of the agricultural and, above all, the structural policy of the Union. Those are the political realities that are likely to determine the positioning in the upcoming debate on policy reform and the own resources system. Since the enlargement process by and large is welcomed and accepted by all countries the political infighting relating to the financing of the enlarged Union is likely to happen between various groups of the present EU 15 rather than between old and new member states. The latter may in some cases gain a strategic influence when deciding with which group to side.
76
Table 14. Financial burden sharing in EU 15 in the year 2000.
Percentage shares and Euro per capita, 1999 prices
Percentage share of EU 15 | Net position | ||||
Total | Total | GNP | As share of | Euro per | |
payments | receipts | GNP | capita | ||
Belgium | 3.9 | 5.6 | 3.0 | 0.85 | 199 |
Denmark | 1.9 | 2.1 | 2.1 | 0.12 | 39 |
Germany | 24.8 | 13.4 | 24.5 | ||
Greece | 1.5 | 7.2 | 1.5 | 3.47 | 414 |
Spain | 7.3 | 14.2 | 7.0 | 0.88 | 127 |
France | 16.5 | 16.1 | 17.0 | ||
Ireland | 1.2 | 3.4 | 1.0 | 1.99 | 447 |
Italy | 12.5 | 14.1 | 13.7 | 0.07 | 14 |
Luxembourg | 0.2 | 1.2 | 0.2 | 4.09 | 1 687 |
Netherlands | 6.2 | 2.9 | 4.8 | ||
Austria | 2.4 | 1.8 | 2.4 | ||
Portugal | 1.4 | 4.2 | 1.3 | 1.95 | 212 |
Finland | 1.4 | 1.8 | 1.5 | 0.19 | 45 |
Sweden | 3.0 | 1.6 | 2.8 | ||
United Kingdom | 15.8 | 10.2 | 17.0 | ||
EU 15 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | ||
Source: Payments and receipts: Allocation of 2000 EU operating expenditure by Member State (EC, September 2001). GNP: Eurostat, European Economy and own extrapolation. Population: UN Population Division (data refer to 2000).
7.3The share of new member states in the financial burden
The new member states will make a small, but significant, contribution to the EU budget. Although the 12 candidate countries will constitute approximately 23 % of the population of the enlarged Union, they will contribute only about 4 % to the GNP measured at market prices. Roughly speaking, this means that the new member states will contribute around 4 % of the total budget of the Union. It is often forgotten in the discussions that that percentage will be applied to the whole budget of the Union (estimated to approximately 110 billion Euro in 2007) and not only to the enlargement costs (estimated to amount to slightly less than 20 billion Euro by 2007). The total payments from new candidates will amount to approximately 5.3 billion Euro. This is of course their contribution to the total
77
The financial burden of the four Berlin net payers, for instance, would be reduced by approximately 1.7 percentage points (mainly attributable to Germany) because of the enlargement and that of the UK with more than 0.8 percentage points. This obviously contributes towards alleviating the burden of additional cost for enlargement.
As can be seen in table 15 and in chart 2 the net positions for the new member states are expected to develop in a very positive manner. We have to emphasize strongly that this is on the assumption that the absorptive capacity of the new member states will develop in the way that is foreseen by the Commission in the proposed CFF and extrapolated by us (see section 5.1.2 above). That assumption is based among other things on the hope that the preaccession support will achieve its goals in preparing the candidate countries for full membership.
There is a large degree of uncertainty surrounding the absorptive capacity of the new member states. Commentators have sometimes expressed concerns that some new member states might end up as net payers because of lacking absorptive capacity. Slovakia and Poland have been mentioned.50 We have had no other option in this study but to rely on the data presented by the Commission.
If some member states should prove to be unable to absorb the available funds, the outcome would be on the one hand that their net position would deteriorate since all member states would have to participate in the Own Resource System from the first day of their membership and on the other hand that the total financing requirements of the EU would be reduced. Depending on the timing this could be a budgeted reduction or take the form of a repayment of funds one year after the underutilization. (In 2001 about 15 billion Euro out of the budget total of almost 100 billion Euro was not used. That sum was credited to the member countries in the budget for 2002, which made the Own Resource quota fall to 0.93 % of GNP for that year. According to the Financial Perspective the quota should have been 1.13 % for that year not counting any enlargement costs.)51
There is at least one additional aspect to consider relating to the budget compensation of the new member states. In the CFF the Commission has proposed that that new members be paid a budgetary compensation in order to prevent their financial
50See for instance an article in ”Die Presse” (Vienna) May 14, 2002 where EU staff responsible for the preaccession programmes in Poland expresses very pessimistic opinions.
51This is the number for which a ceiling of 1.27 % has been set.
78
situation from deteriorating
It is not easy to estimate the net positions of the new member states for the critical years 2003 and 2006, respectively. We know, of course, from the Financial Perspective (EC, 1999) the amount of funds earmarked for
Our own estimates indicate that the need for budgetary compensation according to the criteria suggested by the Commission is marginal and at any rate very far from the annual 800 million of Euro, originally indicated by the Commission in its information note on the CFF.
In our scenarios we have, nevertheless, included the full use of the 800 million margin as defined by the Commission and which we have distributed on all new member states in relation to their GDP shares.
79
7.4Changes in the burden sharing in different scenarios
In table 15 we present the resulting net positions in 2013 as a percentage of GNP/GDP for three of the main scenarios that we calculated.
We note that in both the reform scenarios the present cohesion countries would lose whereas other EU 15 members would gain. Another interesting observation is that in the degressivity scenario Slovenia and the island states would be better off than in the Least Resistance Scenario whereas other new member states would be worse off. The reason is, obviously, that the degressivity would reduce the payments of those countries more than it would reduce the allocation of support payments, in other words the same pattern as for the net payers of EU 15.
Table 15. Net positions 2013 as a share of GNP/GDP in 3 different scenarios.
Percentage shares of GNP/GDP
Least Resistance | Degressivity in | Same rules for all | |
Scenario | direct support | in structural | |
operations | |||
Berlin net payers (D, NL, A, SE) | |||
Net payers without rebate (Dk, F, I, | |||
Fin) | |||
Sum | |||
UK | |||
All net payers | |||
Cohesion countries (Gr, Irl, E, P) | 1.09 | 1.04 | 0.38 |
EU adm ctrs (B, Lx) | 0.84 | 0.87 | 0.99 |
EU 15 total | |||
Baltic (EE, L, Lit) | 5.30 | 5.14 | 5.44 |
Visegrad (Pl, H, CZ, Sl) | 3.78 | 3.67 | 3.92 |
Slovenia | 0.15 | 0.15 | 0.29 |
Island states (C, M) | 0.15 | 0.17 | 0.29 |
BU + RO | 6.58 | 6.45 | 6.72 |
New MS total | 3.89 | 3.79 | 4.03 |
EU enlarged | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 |
Source: Own estimates. |
80
The development over time of the net positions in the Least Resistance Scenario as a share of GNP/GDP is illustrated in charts 1 and 2. Chart 1 shows the development of the present net payers in EU 15. We have underlined above that the inflows of funds (allocation of EU expenditure) will hardly be influenced by the enlargement in the no reform scenario. Changes in net positions are therefore only effected by changes in payments. Chart 1 reveals that while the net position for the net payers that do not enjoy any discount (France, Italy, Denmark and Finland) will deteriorate all through the period, the decline in the net position of the UK as well as of the Berlin net payers (Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden and Austria) would stop by
Chart 2 shows the corresponding development among the net receivers. The positive net position of the cohesion countries and of Belgium and Luxembourg will show a steady decline for the same reason as described above. The net position of Bulgaria, Romania and the Baltic countries will reach numbers that approach or transgress the borders of realism. The net position of the Visegrad countries would reach a plateau around 2009.
The precarious position of the island states and of Slovenia was touched upon above and is clearly illustrated by the chart. The precision of the assumptions that have been made will determine if the curve for the net position in reality will be just above or just below 0 but it is clear that the advantages of membership for those countries do not lie in a bounteous inflow of EU budget funds.
That the net position for new member states as a whole lies a bit below the 4 % limit depends on the fact that the Czech Republic and Hungary (as well as Slovenia, Malta and Cyprus) do not reach the 4 % cap on structural funds as well as on that fact that each member state will have to pay well above 1 % in budget contributions.
81
Chart 1 Net positions of Net Payers in the Least Resistance Scenario 2002 - 2013
0,00 | ||||||||||||
2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | 2009 | 2010 | 2011 | 2012 | 2013 | |
EU 15 total | ||||||||||||
of GNP | UK | |||||||||||
Net payers | ||||||||||||
Percent | ||||||||||||
without discount | ||||||||||||
(DK,F,I,Fin) | ||||||||||||
Berlin net payers | ||||||||||||
(D,NL,A,S) | ||||||||||||
82
Chart 2 Net positions of Net Receivers 2002 - 2013 in the Least Resistance Scenario | ||||||||||||
7,00 | ||||||||||||
Bulgaria,Romania | ||||||||||||
6,00 | ||||||||||||
Baltic countries | ||||||||||||
5,00 | ||||||||||||
GNP/GDP | 4,00 | New MS, total | ||||||||||
Visegrad countries | ||||||||||||
3,00 | ||||||||||||
cent of | ||||||||||||
Per | 2,00 | Cohesion | ||||||||||
ctrs EU 15 | ||||||||||||
1,00 | ||||||||||||
Slovenia | Island states | EU adm countries | ||||||||||
0,00 | ||||||||||||
2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 | 2008 | 2009 | 2010 | 2011 | 2012 | 2013 | |
Source: Own estimates.
83
84
8 Burden sharing – reform issues
8.1The UK rebate
We have several times above demonstrated the distorting impact of the UK rebate on the equity of financing and on the burden sharing. For obvious reasons every attempt to discuss this issue has failed. In the course of Agenda 2000 negotiations and at the meeting of the European Council in Berlin 1999 the UK rebate was reaffirmed in no uncertain terms and explicitly extended also to the enlargement costs. In order to pacify the four largest net payers, which had been trying hard to introduce some limitation on their net payments, it was agreed that those countries would only have to pay 25 % of their “normal” share of the UK rebate as of 2002.52
The reasons for the UK rebate have ceased to exist since long (EC, 1998, p. 25 et passim). The rebate was granted in 1984, at a time when CAP represented about 70 % of the EU budget. England has a relatively small agricultural sector and had, at the time, a relatively low level of prosperity. Its budgetary imbalance, before the rebate, was the largest in the community.
At present there are four countries with the same as or larger imbalance than the UK (Germany, Sweden, the Netherlands and Austria). The structure of the EU budget is now entirely different and will become even more so as enlargement expenditure grows. Member states, which do not pay their full share, are not participating in an equitable fashion in the financing of new expenditure areas, for instance enlargement.
The European Council in Fontainebleau in 1984 decided, “that any member State sustaining a budgetary burden which is excessive in relation to its relative prosperity may benefit from a correction at the
52 In the subsequent negotiations on the promulgation of the own resources decisions there was ample opportunity to haggle over the meaning of the word ”normal”. In the end the concept was defined as the share that the four countries would have paid had they not been granted a financing relief! At the insistence of one member country the reduced share, nevertheless, has to be explicitly computed in two different ways, both obviously giving the same results, as elementary arithmetic will show.
85
appropriate time.”53 In the Agenda 2000 negotiations the four countries mentioned above indicated that they considered their negative budgetary position as “excessive” in relation to their “relative prosperity” according to the Fontainebleau agreement. They proposed substituting a general net correction mechanism (here called NCM) for the UK rebate, which should automatically be applied to any country that met certain criteria. The solution that was found in Berlin was the one described above. Chart 1 and tables show that financially this was a good solution for the benefiting countries.
At present there are 5 out of 15 member states, which do not participate with their full share in financing the EU budget, including the enlargement costs. At the same time there is a group of present or future net payers without any rebate (France, Italy, Denmark and Finland) which, according to our estimates, will face a deteriorating net position (Chart 1, table 15) which will approach
– 0.4 % of GNP a by the end of the period under study. Present cohesion countries, as well as new member states, will pay a larger share towards the budget in relation to their GNP than the UK and the Berlin four. (This can be seen also in table 3 above).
Although none of the candidate countries seems to have objected to this financing pattern it is perhaps doubtful how long the present system will be accepted without major political conflicts. The possibilities for a united front were greater before Berlin than now since the willingness of the Berlin four to reform probably is weaker than before.54 Our model estimates show, nevertheless, that all countries except the UK would benefit from the introduction of a generalized net correction mechanism to replace the
53The Conclusions of the Presidency as quoted in EC, 1998.
54See Pelkmans et al., 2000, and its references (p.139) for some explicit statements about the supposedly diminished reform willingness of the four countries.
55In this rather schematic example, also Austria might be a marginal case depending on which parameter values that are chosen.
86
Table 16. Net positions 2013 under a generalized net correction system.
Percentage shares of GNP
2013 Least Resistance Scenario | |||||
Net position as a share of GNP | |||||
Present | With a generalized Net | ||||
system | Correction Mechanism | ||||
Limit for deploying NCM (net pos as share | |||||
of GNP) | |||||
Rebate on net position above deployment | 50% | 50% | 66% | ||
limit | |||||
Belgium | 0.59 | 0.61 | 0.66 | 0.65 | |
Denmark | |||||
Germany | |||||
Greece | 2.43 | 2.45 | 2.50 | 2.49 | |
Spain | 0.73 | 0.75 | 0.80 | 0.79 | |
France | |||||
Ireland | 0.68 | 0.70 | 0.75 | 0.74 | |
Italy | |||||
Luxembourg | 4.00 | 4.02 | 4.07 | 4.06 | |
Netherlands | |||||
Austria | |||||
Portugal | 1.79 | 1.81 | 1.86 | 1.85 | |
Finland | |||||
Sweden | |||||
United Kingdom | |||||
EU 15 | |||||
New Member States | 3.89 | 3.91 | 3.96 | 3.95 | |
Note: The numbers in the column headings indicate the ceiling which would deploy the NCR and the discount rate, respectively.
The NCM would work so that it would deploy whenever a country reached a net position of a
Those conditions for a NCM are considerably less generous than the ones that determine the UK rebate, which, in principle, is applied on the very first euro of a negative net position. There would still not be any absolute limit for the net positions of any country, but they would grow slower when getting larger than, say,
– 0.40 %.
Table 16 shows this. Even the UK would be better off than in a system where all countries paid their “normal” share. In such a
87
system the UK would have a net position of – 0.61 % compared to
– 0.50 in the examples we have given. The present system would reduce the UK net position to – 0.26.
The improvement for each of 26 countries of the enlarged EU would not be large. Nevertheless, it would be a more equitable system, applicable to all member states and without special favors to individual members.
Despite the outcome of various calculations that can be made, possibilities to change the present system are dubious for obvious, political, reasons. Dresdner Bank, 2001, does not include any UK- rebate in their estimates of the distribution of the financing of the enlargement costs “since a political decision on its future handling has not yet been made.”56 Maybe so, but it is not likely to be taken soon given, for instance, concerns not to irritate the British public opinion, at least not before a referendum on the EMU.
8.2Reforms of the Own Resources System
In the conclusions from the European Council in Berlin the Commission was requested to undertake a review of the functioning of the Own Resources System. The Commission has announced that this review can be expected in 2003. It is too early to speculate what kind of proposals may be made. EC, 1998, makes some analyses and proposals that might well be taken up again. That study makes for instance a review of possible new resources such as a CO2 tax, an increased emphasis on
The political support for an
56Op.cit. p.31. Our translation.
57The seigniorage is, roughly speaking, the profit of the central banks and, in this case, the ECB. This profit is generated as interest yield on bonds and other assets held by the central bank as counterpart to the monetary base, which it creates itself. Part of this profit is delivered to the reasury and has been of great help to some countries in achieving the established balance criteria for the government finances. Only when entering the government budget does the seignorage have an influence on the real economy. It can be mentioned that the funds financing the Swedish
88
supranational features of the Union and threaten the democratic sovereignty of the citizens over their taxes. Theoretical niceties apart, we find it difficult to see any difference between a straightforward EU taxation and the present system. Also under the present system countries have to pay whatever results from the budget process and their possibilities to influence this are strictly limited to their influence on the expenditure development. An EU- tax could be collected and administered by the national tax administrations in the same way as the present contribution payments. We are nevertheless happy to abstain from entering this minefield in advance of possible proposals from the Commission.
A much simpler reform, which has been discussed time and again, would be to substitute the present system with a simpler one, based purely on
The collection of the
Table 17 shows the differences between the estimated payments 2013 according to the present Own Resources System and a clean
89
Table 17. Total payments 2013 in a
Millions of euro, 1999 prices
Present system | Difference | ||
Belgium | 3 754 | 3 774 | 19 |
Denmark | 2 566 | 2 620 | 53 |
Germany | 28 734 | 28 599 | |
Greece | 2 086 | 2 075 | |
Spain | 9 193 | 9 144 | |
France | 21 865 | 21 749 | |
Ireland | 1 460 | 1 452 | |
Italy | 17 228 | 17 516 | 288 |
Luxembourg | 299 | 298 | |
Netherlands | 5 672 | 5 645 | |
Austria | 2 854 | 2 841 | |
Portugal | 1 692 | 1 683 | |
Finland | 1 915 | 1 926 | 10 |
Sweden | 3 294 | 3 333 | 39 |
United Kingdom | 13 509 | 13 506 | |
EU 15 | 116 121 | 116 159 | 38 |
Sources: Own estimates.
Germany and France would benefit from a switch to a purely
It has not been possible to include the new member states in this example since there are no data available concerning the
90
8.3What is relative prosperity?
The Fontainebleau agreement gives countries the possibility to enjoy a correction for budgetary imbalances if their burden is “excessive” in relation to their “relative prosperity.” But how should the level of prosperity be measured? Differences in price levels between countries and fluctuating exchange rates make a comparison of the level of income per head a very uncertain business. International organizations, including the Commission and EUROSTAT regularly calculate purchasing power parities (ppp) to be used for international comparisons. The theory behind the
This is not the place to go into the intricacies of estimating ppp. When measuring relative prosperity the
58 The eligibility of regions for Objective 1 support is calculated in
91
Table 18. Payments and net positions 2013 in a system based on purchasing power parities.
Least Resistance Scenario. Percentage distribution and share of GNP
Distr. of payments | Net position share GNP | |||
In the | In a ppp- | In the | In a ppp- | |
normal | based | normal | based | |
system | system | system | system | |
Berlin net payers (D, NL, A, SE) | 32.9 | 28.8 | ||
Net payers without rebate (DK, F, I, Fin) | 35.3 | 32.1 | ||
Sum | 68.2 | 60.9 | ||
UK | 11.0 | 10.3 | ||
All net payers | 79.2 | 71.2 | ||
Cohesion countries (Gr, Irl, E, P) | 11.7 | 13.2 | 1.09 | 0.72 |
EU adm ctrs (B, Lx) | 3.3 | 3.2 | 0.84 | 0.81 |
EU 15 total | 94.2 | 87.6 | ||
Baltic (EE, L, Lit) | 0.3 | 0.7 | 5.30 | 1.58 |
Visegrad (Pl, H, CZ, Sl) | 4.2 | 8.5 | 3.78 | 1.16 |
Slovenia | 0.3 | 0.4 | 0.15 | |
Island states (C, M) | 0.2 | 0.3 | 0.15 | |
BU + RO | 0.7 | 2.5 | 6.58 | 1.03 |
New MS total | 5.8 | 12.4 | 3.89 | 1.08 |
EU enlarged | 100.0 | 100.0 | 0.00 | 0.00 |
Source: Own estimates based on UNDP/World Bank data.
In a pure
Both OECD/Eurostat and the World Bank compute
92
considerably lower. The rankings of Sweden differ most of all countries: while ranked as number 2 in GNP/capita calculated at official exchange rates its ranking is only number 9 when
8.4Partial
We have discussed, in chapter 6, the important reform requirements concerning CAP and the structural policy. The aim of those reforms are to achieve more efficient and adequate policies for supporting agriculture, to even out income differences between regions and countries and to reduce the budgetary costs of the Union. There are also other reform proposals, which aim directly at the distribution of the financial burden. Those have to do with
The question of whether a policy area should be the responsibility of the community or the national level is connected with the principle of subsidiarity. This principle says that higher levels of public authority should be involved only when their intervention is deemed necessary for achieving objectives that would be out of reach for lower levels. (Grevi, 2001, p.4). According to this principle the Maastricht Treaty states: “In areas which do not fall within its exclusive competence, the Community shall take action, in accordance with the principle of subsidiarity, only if and insofar as the objectives of the proposed action cannot be sufficiently achieved by the Member States.” Meanwhile the Nice Treaty on the future of the Union asks for further clarity on “how to establish and monitor a more precise delimitation of competencies between the European Union and the Member States, reflecting the principle of subsidiarity”.59
The
There is another, more practical aspect, of whether a policy area should be in the hands of the Union or the national governments.
59All quotes from Grevi, 2001.
60One government representative believes that if such a catalogue had existed earlier the EU would not have been able to deal with environmental issues, which were not predominant in the sixties. (Dagens Nyheter, Stockholm, 02 05 30).
93
To understand this we start by looking at table 19. This time data are taken from statistics from the Commission rather than from our own estimates.
A rule of thumb might be that the larger the gap between the share of payment and the share of allocated expenditure, the more interested a country would be in partial or complete renationalization. Obviously, the reduction of contribution payments that a
We have also included here the interesting policy area “Internal policies”. This area covers items such as training, youth, culture, energy, environment, consumer protection, internal market and research and development. The first thing we notice is the extremely strong position of Belgium and Luxembourg. We hypothesize that the presence of the EU central institutions benefits those countries not only through the allocation of administrative expenditure but also through easier access to the internal policy funds. (A detailed breakdown shows that Belgium retains this strong position in all the
94
Table 19. The relation between member countries shares of allocated expenditure and of payments in 2000.
Agriculture | Structural operations | Internal policy | |
Belgium | 0.80 | 0.47 | 4.07 |
Denmark | 1.68 | 0.26 | 1.84 |
Germany | 0.55 | 0.54 | 0.62 |
Greece | 4.00 | 6.31 | 2.19 |
Spain | 1.79 | 2.43 | 0.75 |
France | 1.25 | 0.51 | 0.74 |
Ireland | 3.50 | 2.50 | 1.42 |
Italy | 0.95 | 1.43 | 0.85 |
Luxembourg | 0.50 | 0.00 | 7.50 |
Netherlands | 0.69 | 0.33 | 1.17 |
Austria | 1.00 | 0.36 | 0.84 |
Portugal | 1.07 | 5.80 | 2.47 |
Finland | 1.20 | 1.33 | 1.47 |
Sweden | 0.65 | 0.26 | 1.03 |
United Kingdom | 0.68 | 0.73 | 1.00 |
EU 15 | 1.00 | 1.00 | 1.00 |
Source: Own estimates based on EC, September 2001.
Note: The numbers in the table are calculated as each country´s share of the allocated expenditure in the policy area divided by its share of payments to the EU budget. The number 4.07 for Internal policy in Belgium, for instance, indicates that Belgium´s share of the allocations of internal policy funds is more than 4 times larger than its share of payments to the EU budget.
Since the whole area “Internal policy” in 2000 only amounted to 6.5 % of total allocated expenditure we are not talking of any large amounts of money. But it is interesting to note that this policy area where funds are largely directed towards institutions, enterprises, organizations or local government the distribution pattern is entirely different from other policy areas. Net payers, which are strong in this area, should be interested in moving resources from structural operations to internal policy. Tarschys, 2000, has shown that most of the success stories of structural operations are in areas that could as well have been placed under “Internal policy”. The Commission’s guidelines for the structural policy 2000 – 2006 emphasize, among other things, environmental policy, equality between men and women, energy, information technology, research and development, tourism, culture and services. A transfer from one policy area to the other with accompanying change in the system of distribution of funds might open up interesting possibilities for some of the present high net payers as well as for some of the emerging ones.
95
We can take this reasoning one step further and point out that a reversal – or perhaps rather a reinterpretation – of the subsidiarity principle in the form of transferring more policy areas from the national budgets to the Union might be to the benefit of certain member states. Environmental policy and defense policy might be such areas.
We will end this section by pointing out that a net payer policy aiming at maximizing the return flow of allocated expenditure may turn out to be very counterproductive. If a country is a very strong net payer in one area it will almost certainly be preferable to sacrifice the inflow of funds for the benefit of reforms, reduction or renationalization of the policy area. In the field of structural policy we can easily identify some such cases. Table 19 shows that efforts of countries such as Denmark, the Netherlands, Austria and Sweden to increase or even maintain their structural support would be counterproductive if it meant jeopardizing the possibilities of reform, particularly in the
8.5Towards a more equitable burden sharing in a larger EU
In this section we will make a somewhat subjective assessment of the results of the analysis made earlier in this chapter. This assessment will be formulated as policy recommendations.
The present system for sharing financing responsibility and for allocating expenditure from the EU budget is a motley quilt with seams that threaten to burst when it should cover 27 member states of the most varying character. In the perspective of the enlargement, the aim must be to create a system of financing and allocating expenditure that is sustainable in the long run, regarded as fair by all participants and robust enough in face of external shocks.
The present Own Resources System creates inequalities in the responsibility for financing the
61 But see section 6.1.2 above on the links between Brussels and the regions.
96
The aim must be to ensure that all countries pay an equitable share and that, in particular, that new member states would no longer pay more than the richest countries in relative terms. All net payers should also enjoy equal treatment and those that have only lately emerged as net payers, or perhaps will do so in the future, should not be treated differently from the classical net contributors.
The problem nevertheless remains that there is no upper limit for payment obligations and, in practice, no lower limit for negative net positions for a group of 6 – 9 countries out of 27 members. Even the 1.27 % (or now: 1.24 % of GNI)62 is not sacrosanct. As the voting share of the net receivers in the Council gets bigger, as more decisions are taken by qualified majority and as more budgetary power is transferred to the European Parliament, the upward pressure on expenditure is likely to grow. Of course, any one country will still have the formal possibility to veto budgetary decisions. But political pressure, blocking minorities by net receivers and tactical alliances between net receivers and the one or other net contributor may make it difficult or impossible for small countries with net payer status to prevent drastic expansion of expenditure. Some kind of automatic stabilizer could alleviate those risks. A generalized net correction mechanism would probably be the most appropriate instrument. Its parameters can be negotiated and no absolute limit of the payment responsibility would be involved. All member states would be eligible as soon as they meet the
A generalized net correction mechanism may also help net payers, in particular small countries that are important contributors such as the Netherlands, Austria and the Nordic countries, to abstain from
62 For an explanation of how this has been calculated see document COM (2001) 801 final, available online in the Eurolex datase or, in a more cursory way, in document COM (2002) 86 final: Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament – Adaptation of the ceiling of own resources and of the ceiling for appropriations for commitments following the entry into force of Decision 2000/597/EC, Euratom (COM (2001) 801 final of 28.12.2001.
97
policy (perhaps directed at the national level) and a transfer of other viable parts to the Internal policy area.63 Such measures, while improving the efficiency of the regional policy, particularly for the new member states, may be to the benefit of the net payers. They may also be able to identify areas, which could be transferred from the national to the Union budget, thereby easing the pressure on national budgets while at the same time improving their net positions. However, since this would be a
An alternative to a generalized net correction mechanism might be to introduce elements from purchasing power parity measurements of the level of prosperity when determining the base for payment responsibility. However, the methodology for pppcalculations is probably not yet well enough established to play such an important role. In addition, it might not be advisable to charge new member states with a higher payment share during the transition period to full integration in the Union, even if that would better reflect their real economic strength. The pppestimates of GDP per capita must be an element to consider nevertheless in assessing any proposal for reform of the payment system.
Failing more radical reforms, the present
There could be a political price to pay for a reform that would abolish the system of rebates. That price would probably take the form of delaying or hindering the expansion of the EMU to cover all countries of the Union, particularly the UK and its followers. Before letting such considerations stop a reform a very careful analysis should be made of the
Any forthcoming proposal from the Commission on a possible taxation at the Union level should be carefully considered on its own merits and not rejected offhand as an infringement upon national sovereignty. Depending on the nature of such proposal, it may not be very different in real terms from the present system in
63 See Tarschys, 2000, for examples of such areas.
98
terms of national sovereignty but possibly more effective and equitable.
99
100
9 An eroded union?
9.1The candidate countries are small with a very low level of income
The budgetary costs of the planned enlargement of the EU should certainly not be underestimated. As we have indicated above there might be risks for an uncontrolled expansion of expenditure in the agricultural as well as in the structural operations field if there are no significant reforms of those policy areas. The increased number of net receivers and new, potentially budget expansionary, coalitions in the Council cannot be excluded.
Nevertheless, the overall impression of our estimates is that the enlargement costs, also in the time perspective of the next Financial Perspective, would be possible to absorb and to manage by the net payers, particularly when considering the likely macroeconomic gains of the expansion. The enlargement should not in the first instance be regarded as a budgetary or macroeconomic issue but there is every reason to consider whether it might raise other problems than those that can be measured in Euro.
We know that this is the case. Already in section 8.2 above, we have discussed the necessity to reform the Own Resources System in order to prevent increasing inequality among members, which would lead to tensions not only between net payers and receivers but also between different groups of net payers. The necessity of reforms of the agricultural as well as the structural policy has also been discussed and is already a hot topic on the international agenda.
Nevertheless, we might say that those problems exist already today. The enlargement may aggravate them but they are certainly not caused by the need to accommodate new members states. There are, on the other hand, other problems that are directly related to the enlargement, for example the inadequacy of the institutional structures and the increasing administrative costs (such as the future language regime!).
101
It might be useful to put the enlargement in a wider perspective. As illustrated in table 20, the candidate countries – the prospective new member states – are very small compared to the present Union. True, they would represent about 22 % of the population of the enlarged EU but only slightly more than 4 % of the GDP or, when measured at ppp, around 10 %. Two of the prospective new member states, Poland and Romania, would contribute almost 60 % of the population and as much as 40 or 50 % of GDP of the new member states depending on whether the calculation is made at official exchange rates or using ppp.
The small size of the candidate countries could be seen as a positive factor from the point of view of the ability of the union to absorb new members. But the difference between the candidates and the present members is almost breathtaking when we look, for instance, at the income levels. This is illustrated in table 21. The island states have a GDP/capita that is higher than the lowest value of EU 15 (Portugal) and even Slovenia slightly exceeds that value, but only when GDP is measured at ppp. However, at official exchange rates, which is the measure that will determine the contributions of the new members to the EU budget even Slovenia is only at a level of 88 % of the lowest value in EU 15 (Greece). All candidate countries together have a GDP/capita of 16 % of the average of EU 15. Seven out of the 12 countries have a GDP/capita below 20 % of the EU 15 average!
Table 20. Share of the candidate countries in an enlarged EU.
Percentage shares based on 1999 data
Population | GDP at official | GDP at ppp | |
exchange rates | |||
10 countries as a share of EU 25 | 16.6 | 3.7 | 8.1 |
12 countries as a share of EU 27 | 21.9 | 4.2 | 9.9 |
Poland as a share of 12 new member states | 36.6 | 31.1 | 35.7 |
Romania as a share of 12 new member states | 21.3 | 9.0 | 14.9 |
Source: Derived from UNDP, Human Development Report 2001.
102
Tabell 21. | GDP per capita in candidate countries in relation to | |||
EU 15. | ||||
Index numbers, 1999 data | ||||
Average EU 15 = 100 | Lowest value in EU 15 = 100 | |||
At official | At ppp estimates | At official | At ppp estimates | |
exchange rates | exchange rates | |||
Bulgaria | 7 | 23 | 14 | 34 |
Cyprus | 49 | 82 | 99 | 118 |
Czech Republic | 23 | 59 | 45 | 85 |
Estonia | 16 | 39 | 33 | 56 |
Hungary | 21 | 52 | 43 | 75 |
Lithuania | 13 | 30 | 25 | 43 |
Latvia | 11 | 29 | 23 | 41 |
Malta | 51 | 86 | 103 | 124 |
Poland | 18 | 38 | 35 | 55 |
Romania | 7 | 27 | 13 | 39 |
Slovenia | 44 | 71 | 88 | 103 |
Slovakia | 16 | 48 | 32 | 69 |
New MS total | 16 | 39 | 31 | 57 |
Source: UNDP Human Development Report 2001.
Disregarding for a moment the island states, Slovenia is the richest candidate country and has a GDP/capita of 44 % of the average of EU 15. Obviously, if we look at the ppp data instead this picture would be somewhat modified but not to an extent that would change the rather dismal picture.64
This situation cannot be compared with previous enlargements of the Union. At their time of accession, Ireland had a GNP/capita reaching 58 % of the average of the countries that now make up EU 15. For Spain the corresponding number was 56 %, for Greece 33 % and for Portugal 31 %. Only Cyprus, Malta and Slovenia are presently in a situation similar to the one of Portugal at the time of accession.65
64Figures in the Strategy Report 2001 (EC, November 2001) are marginally lower than those estimated by us!
65In 1999 Ireland was above the average of EU 15, Spain at around 76 % and Greece and Portugal slightly over 50 %.
103
9.2Are the candidate countries more developed than national account numbers seem to indicate?
Is it possible that it is mainly with respect to the degree of economic development that the candidate countries are severely lagging behind present member states? Two
The UNDP index measures not only economic development but also a number of factors relating to life expectancy, health and education. Comparable data are available for more than 150 countries of the world. In order to make correct comparisons we have adjusted the UNDP data slightly. We consider only the countries with the 100 highest
The same picture is emerging if we compare the differences between the ranking of the candidate countries and Greece, the present EU member with the lowest
66 The first three countries in 2001 were Norway, Australia and Canada.
104
except the four mentioned countries where the difference in HDI is clearly smaller.
We can make a cautious comparison of the development of the HDI over time: since 1995 there seems to have been significant improvement in the HDI rankings of Poland, Hungary and Latvia.67
The evidence from this material is not too clear. Nevertheless we have been able to identify a small number of candidate countries where the gap to the present EU in terms of human resources might be smaller than the gap in income. If true this should facilitate the integration and
Trade between the candidate countries and EU 15 has increased impressively after the fall of the old system. However, the exports from the EU have increased much faster than the imports and large trade deficits have been created in most candidate countries. We will not go into an analysis of the real economic impact of this imbalance or of the fact that most candidate countries have an industrial and export structure that is different from the EU 15. We have already in section 4.3 referred to a study (Egger et al., 2001), which discusses the competitive strength of Eastern and Southern Europe, respectively. A study by A. Smith, University of London, (Smith, 2000), undertakes a detailed review of the revealed comparative advantages. The study finds that in particular that the industry of Latvia, Lithuania, Bulgaria and Romania would not be competitive on the European market and threatened by high costs of restructuring. We note that three of those countries are among those that we have identified above as countries with possible latent human resources capacities. We should not speculate too far on a possible connection – taken at face value one could perhaps say that this would facilitate a necessary restructuring process.
The assessment of the Commission is found in the Strategy Report (EC, November 2001). With respect to the requirement of being able to meet the competitive pressure the Commission concludes:
67 When making thoses comparison adjustments have been made for the different number of countries included in 1995 and 1999, respectively.
105
“The Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia are functioning market economies. There are substantial economic differences among these countries, but provided they continue with, and in some cases reinforce, a number of differing measures detailed in each Regular Report, they should be able to cope with competitive pressure and market forces within the Union in the near term. “
Nevertheless this assessment is qualified by a long and distressing list of improvements that need to be made by the candidate countries in all the central areas of the economy.
We can sidelight the by necessity somewhat optimistic assessment of the Commission by looking at some data from the World Competitiveness Yearbook (IMD, 2002). This yearbook, which is compiled by the International Institute for Management Development in Lausanne, Switzerland, contains a competitiveness “scoreboard” where the participating countries are ranked according to a large number of factors. Competitiveness is given a very broad, and deep, definition where unit labor cost is only one part. Other factors are openness, governance, finance, infrastructure, technology, quality of the labor force, institutions etc. The estimates are based on very detailed studies of enterprises in each of the participating countries.
The scoreboard shows, for instance, that of the EU 15 countries only Finland, the Netherlands and Ireland have a higher ranking of competitiveness than of GDP/capita. All other EU members have a lower ranking which is exactly what we would expect since the comparison now is made with highly productive countries with relatively low average income such as the Republic of Korea, the Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan etc. Accordingly, it is remarkable that the three mentioned EU countries apparently have been able to compensate their cost disadvantage, measured as GDP/capita, with other factors that influence competitiveness positively. We would now expect – indeed hope forthe candidate countries to translate their very low level of GDP/capita into a high competitiveness ranking. Data are available only for 6 of the candidate countries (Estonia, Hungary, Czech Republic, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia) and in all those cases the country ranking with respect to competitiveness is indeed higher than the ranking according to GDP/capita. In so far as we can draw any conclusion
106
from these indications, it would be that the competitiveness scoreboard, at least for these 6 countries, would tend to support the positive assessment of the Commission.68
9.3The invisible problems
When the European Union has been enlarged from 15 to 27 member countries, its GNP per capita will have fallen by approximately 20 %. Most of the new member countries will be at a level of economic development far below the present membership. The gaps between the richest and poorest members will be larger than it has ever been, even at the time of the
The picture that we just have drawn is based on factors that can relatively easy be quantified and measured. The most important prerequisite for membership, the adoption and implementation of the acquis communautaire, concerns, on the other hand, factors that to a large extent are
We have to modify the statement above to some extent. The screening of the acquis focuses on the legislation that has been implemented, the institutions that have been built up etc. Those factors can, of course, in a sense be measured and accounted for and this is also done in the strategy reports, albeit largely on the basis of information from the candidate countries themselves. The intrinsic quality and the efficiency of the administrative and institutional adjustment can, on the other hand, hardly be assessed through the screening process. We might recall that the problems in the candidate countries (and in the Soviet Union) under the old system hardly were caused by the fact that the number of governmental institutions was too small or that comprehensive legislation was missing.
68 This result is different from the one found two years ago in Karlsson, 2001, and more positive for the candidate countries. One caveat: participation in the surveys and the scoreboard is voluntary and tends to include mainly countries that expect a good showing!
107
Pelkmans et al., 2000, point to the risk of erosion of the interior market and that the enlargement might lead to member states becoming less disciplined and putting more emphasis on national preferences and exceptions from the common framework. The system of sanctions that exists could then easily collapse. With detailed statistics of breaches or unsatisfactory implementation of the acquis communautaire the authors try to show that such a process of erosion is already under way and likely will be reinforced by the accession of the central European countries “where traditions of legalism, rather than equivalence to achieve the objectives of law, are so prevalent.”69
In their most recent Strategy Paper (EC, November 2001) the Commission talks in optimistic wordings of the progress made in the candidate countries and which has been observed through the screening process. The presentation of detailed results, country by country, partly gives a different impression. Even in the most advanced candidate countries serious problems remain and in many cases little progress seems to have been made in comparison to previous reports. Deficiencies in human rights and treatment of minorities, trafficking and persistent corruption seem to be particularly serious problems. But even at the economic level the Commission finds that not all candidate countries have succeeded to come closer to the EU and that economic inequalities within the countries have increased. In the Report 2000 it is explicitly stated that the privatization process has facilitated the creation of a new economic elite, stemming from the previous nomenclatura.70
Long transition arrangement for the free movement of labor has in principle already been agreed on. The negotiations are likely to bring about further exceptions, border controls and transitional arrangement as, for instance, in agriculture for veterinary and phytosanitary reasons. Every exception, every special clause, every obstacle for the “four freedoms”71 will contribute to an erosion of the Union.
The circumstances that have been discussed above should of course not detract from the remarkable economic, social and political progress that has been achieved in most candidate countries since the system change. The Commission rightly underlines that most countries fully meet the Copenhagen criteria, that most have a functioning market economy and that the political
69Pelkmans et al., 2000, p.68
70EC, November 2001, chapter III, section 2 a.
71Free movement for people, capital, goods and services.
108
stability in Europe has increased significantly. As we have already pointed out, trade between Eastern and Western Europe has shown a very dynamic development after the change of economic system. Most candidate countries have shown an impressive economic growth, albeit from the very low level caused by the implosion of the system of central planning. We agree, nevertheless, with Pelkmans et al., 2000, on the risk for an erosion of the union. We believe that this risk is particularly large in areas where the visible manifestation of the implementation of the acquis communautaire mainly is of an institutional or administrative character or perhaps in the form of illusive indicators, the impact of which cannot really be screened at all. Examples of such chapters are, for instance, chapter 24 Justice and Home Affairs, which covers border control, illegal migration, drugs trafficking and money laundering, organized crime, police and judicial
One of the basic principles of the approach to enlargement has been that all members of the enlarged union must be treated equally, after negotiated transition periods, which were to be kept as short as possible. This is also one of the reasons why the Commission and the present membership have insisted so strictly on the full adoption of the acquis communautaire in the candidate countries. (This includes membership in the EMU although, of course, every member state will have to meet also the special criteria established for the monetary cooperation before becoming full members.) Although there is likely to be a lot of lip service to the principle of not having any
72 Most easily available on the www under http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/ report2001/index.htm
109
integration in certain areas, have created the concept of
It would be an important charge for the Convention on the Future of Europe to propose ways and means to prevent a future erosion of the Union as well as ways and means to overcome tensions created by a different willingness or capability of member states to forge ahead with European integration. Finally, it will be up to the Intergovernmental Conference, foreseen for 2004, to show the political courage to take the necessary decisions. Policy reform, institutional reform and a
We have not, in this study, discussed other prospective candidate countries. (Turkey is already an official candidate country.) In case of a successful enlargement it would be difficult, and certainly not desirable, to leave out countries like Croatia, FYROM, Serbia/Montenegro, Albania and Moldova once they would meet the Copenhagen criteria. Can a political and economic entity that spans from Luxembourg (highest GDP/capita) or Sweden (highest
110
Appendix 1: Net positions and ability to pay
To the extent possible this study uses the same definition and methods as the EC in the study Agenda 2000 Financing the European Union, 1998 (EC, 1998) to which the reader is referred for detailed explanations. This has been done in order to facilitate international comparison, particularly with estimates by the EC. More precisely, we have used the concept of the
The choice of definition has some important implications, particularly when it comes to assessing the payments and net positions.73 The following observations should be made in this context:
The ORR method does not count the traditional own resources (TOR), i.e. mainly custom duties, as ”national contributions” to the EU budget. The reason for this is that importers may utilize ports in other countries while the country at the border collects the custom duties. The TOR that are included in the ORR balance are therefore not the actual amount that a country collects and delivers to the EU budget but an imputed amount, calculated as the total TOR of the Union multiplied by the share of each country of the total VAT- and
73 When calculating ex post budget balances, these difficulties are compounded by the need to choose between cash or accrual data.
111
This method is not undisputed. Some countries, notably the Netherlands, claim that the custom duties collected should be seen as a return on national investment in infrastructure, e.g. in ports. They should therefore be considered as a national contribution to the EU budget. This is an example of ”regional arbitrariness” of a tax and in this context sometimes called ”The Rotterdam Effect”. The EC refers to studies showing that 27 % of the custom duties levied in the Netherlands and 31 % of those levied in Antwerp are related to final consumption of goods in other member countries. (EC 1998, p. 44; Verbeke et al. March 1998). However, the Dutch side has pointed out that the 73 % of the customs duties that would represent a burden to the Dutch economy, would still lead to a Dutch share of all EU TOR that is at least twice the normal one.
We know very little about the distribution of TOR in an enlarged Union. We have assumed that each new MS collects TOR in the same relation to its GNP as the EU 15 average.
A certain amount of the EU budget cannot be allocated to its member countries because it is spent outside the Union. We are talking about less than 10 % of the budget that goes to external expenditure, including
In our view the use of the “accounting balance” definition would give a better view of the real financial burden sharing among the EU member states. With this definition, TOR payments are considered as paid by the country that transfers them to the EU budget. The total EU expenditure, including external expenditure, is taken into account. The payments that are required to finance the external expenditure (e.g.
112
have left the EU” (EC 1998, p 68), a somewhat contrived argument, in our opinion.
Despite the arguments in favor of the accounting definition, the “UK rebate balance” - the ORR definition - has been used in this study, mainly to facilitate comparisons with other studies, notably from the EC.
The table below shows the impact of using different methods on some countries, which are mainly influenced by the choice of definition. The ORR method underestimates, for instance the Dutch net position by more than 0.2 % of GNP and the German and Swedish ones by 0.04 à 0.05 % of GNP. It must be remembered, however, that it is only the net position that is underor overestimated; the budgetary payments (as well as the allocated expenditure) are not affected by this difference in definitions.
The concept of “operational balance” is of little interest to most countries – it has been advanced mainly by countries to which a large share of administrative expenditure is allocated. With that definition, payments are considerably reduced whereas allocated expenditure is affected only marginally, except for Belgium and Luxembourg. This definition is doubly disadvantageous for large net payers: not only do their contributions seem to diminish relative to the countries which host the EU administration but their net positions are calculated on a lower level of EU expenditure than in other definitions and hence less negative than in reality. Belgium succeeded to achieve that the Commission must show this concept “for presentational purposes” (see, for instance, EC, September 2001) but we cannot see that the concept has any analytical or operational (sic!) value.
As pointed out above, the concept of “accounting balance” would give a more accurate picture of the burden sharing within the Union. That definition is therefore of particular interest to those countries that have an over proportional share of TOR. This is illustrated in the following table.
113
Appendix table 1. Net positions in 2013 calculated with different definitions.
Shares of GNP in the Least Resistance Scenario
Definition of budgetary | Bel- | Germany | The | UK | Sweden | EU 15 |
balance | gium | Netherlands | ||||
”ORR” | 0.59 | |||||
”Accounting” | 0.35 | |||||
”Operational/ORR” |
From the numbers in the table, it is easy to understand why these rather technical issues attract a certain amount of interest in the negotiations between the EU members.
114
Appendix 2: Additional tables
Source material for scenario calculations:
The Financial Perspective
The Common Financial Framework for Negotiations (EC, 30.1.2001, ref 9). All enlargement scenarios use those figures for
Own extrapolations for the period
Distribution of allocated expenditure by countries:
Agriculture: Material from the Swedish Ministry of Agriculture Structural funds: Material from the Swedish Business Develop-
ment Agency (NUTEK)
Other expenditure: Own assumptions as described in the text
Purchasing power parities: UNDP (UN, 2001) and the World Bank (UN, 2002, ref 16).
Population data: United Nations Population Division (UN, 2002, ref 15).
Competitiveness indicators: The World Competitiveness Yearbook 2002, International Institute for Management Development (IMD, 2002).
115
Appendix table 2. The benchmark scenario (no enlargement), commitments and payments.
Millions of euro, 1999 prices
2000 | 2002 | 2004 | 2006 | post- | |
2006 | |||||
Commitments | |||||
Agriculture | 40 920 | 43 900 | 41 084 | 42 932 | 43 788 |
Structural operations | 32 045 | 30 872 | 29 602 | 29 205 | 29 205 |
Internal policy | 5 930 | 6 150 | 6 370 | 6 600 | 6 600 |
Administration | 4 560 | 4 700 | 4 900 | 5 100 | 5 100 |
3 120 | 3 120 | 3 120 | 3 120 | 3 120 | |
Other expenditure | 5 450 | 5 220 | 4 990 | 5 010 | 5 010 |
Total | 92 025 | 93 962 | 90 066 | 91 967 | 92 823 |
Ratio payments/commitments1 | 0.95 | 1.01 | 1.00 | 0.98 | 0.99 |
Payments: | |||||
Agriculture | 40 920 | 43 900 | 41 084 | 42 932 | 43 788 |
Structural operations | 30 343 | 31 055 | 29 721 | 28 507 | 28 772 |
Internal policy | 5 615 | 6 186 | 6 396 | 6 442 | 6 502 |
Administration | 4 560 | 4 700 | 4 900 | 5 100 | 5 100 |
2 954 | 3 138 | 3 133 | 3 045 | 3 074 | |
Other expenditure | 5 208 | 5 247 | 5 008 | 4 900 | 4 942 |
Total | 89 600 | 94 227 | 90 241 | 90 926 | 92 177 |
Total paym. as % of GNP | 1.09 | 1.11 | 1.01 | 0.97 | 0.89 |
1 Excluding agriculture, reserves and administration.
Sources: The Financial Perspective 2000 2006 (EC, 1999). Input from Swedish sources.
116
Appendix table 3. Enlargement costs by country group in a Least Resistance Scenario.
Millions of euro, 1999 prices
2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 | |
Berlin net payers (D, NL, A, SE) | 853 | 2 802 | 5 501 | 7 330 | 8 626 |
Net payers without rebate (DK, F, I, Fin) | 657 | 2 540 | 5 258 | 7 047 | 8 405 |
Sum | 1 510 | 5 342 | 10 759 | 14 376 | 17 031 |
UK | 442 | 1 510 | 2 798 | 3 675 | 4 168 |
All net payers | 1 952 | 6 852 | 13 557 | 18 051 | 21 200 |
Cohesion countries (Gr, Irl, E, P) | 222 | 841 | 1 732 | 2 319 | 2 763 |
EU adm ctrs (B, Lx) | 61 | 236 | 489 | 655 | 781 |
EU 15 total | 2 235 | 7 930 | 15 778 | 21 026 | 24 744 |
Baltic (EE, L, Lit) | 286 | 316 | 350 | 390 | 422 |
Visegrad countries (Pl, H, CZ, Sl) | 3 543 | 3 923 | 4 343 | 4 840 | 5 235 |
Slovenia | 267 | 296 | 327 | 365 | 394 |
Island states (C, M) | 164 | 182 | 202 | 225 | 243 |
BU + RO | 0 | 0 | 734 | 818 | 885 |
New MS total | 4 260 | 4 717 | 5 956 | 6 637 | 7 180 |
EU enlarged | 6 495 | 12 646 | 21 734 | 27 663 | 31 923 |
Source: Own estimates. |
Appendix table 4. Total payments to the EU budget by country group in a Least Resistance Scenario.
Millions of euro, 1999 prices
2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 | |
Berlin net payers (D, NL, A, SE) | 31 888 | 34 141 | 37 275 | 39 221 | 40 554 |
Net payers without rebate (DK, F, I, Fin) | 33 828 | 36 390 | 39 563 | 42 100 | 43 575 |
Sum | 65 716 | 70 530 | 76 839 | 81 321 | 84 129 |
UK | 11 591 | 12 079 | 13 531 | 13 232 | 13 509 |
All net payers | 77 307 | 82 610 | 90 370 | 94 553 | 97 637 |
Cohesion countries (Gr, Irl, E, P) | 11 221 | 12 061 | 13 105 | 13 934 | 14 430 |
EU adm ctrs (B, Lx) | 3 148 | 3 386 | 3 681 | 3 916 | 4 054 |
EU 15 total | 91 676 | 98 056 | 107 155 | 112 403 | 116 121 |
Baltic (EE, L, Lit) | 286 | 316 | 350 | 390 | 422 |
Visegrad countries (Pl, H, CZ, Sl) | 3 543 | 3 923 | 4 343 | 4 840 | 5 235 |
Slovenia | 267 | 296 | 327 | 365 | 394 |
Island states (C, M) | 164 | 182 | 202 | 225 | 243 |
BU + RO | 0 | 0 | 734 | 818 | 885 |
New MS total | 4 260 | 4 717 | 5 956 | 6 637 | 7 180 |
EU enlarged | 95 936 | 102 773 | 113 111 | 119 040 | 123 300 |
Source: Own estimates. |
117
Appendix table 5. Net positions by country group in a Least Resistance Scenario.
Millions of euro, 1999 prices. UK rebate definition
2004 | 2006 | 2007 | 2010 | 2013 | |
Berlin net payers (D, NL, A, SE) | |||||
Net payers without rebate (DK, F, I, Fin) | |||||
Sum | |||||
UK | |||||
All net payers | |||||
Cohesion countries (Gr, Irl, E, P) | 17 122 | 15 877 | 15 076 | 14 246 | 13 748 |
EU adm ctrs (B, Lx) | 3 444 | 3 485 | 3 366 | 3 130 | 2 992 |
EU 15 total | |||||
Baltic (EE, L, Lit) | 453 | 1 021 | 1 251 | 1 666 | 1 949 |
Visegrad countries (Pl, H, CZ, Sl) | 1 676 | 6 510 | 11 572 | 15 086 | 17 223 |
Slovenia | 27 | 40 | 58 | 51 | |
Island states (C, M) | 70 | 40 | 43 | 31 | |
BU + RO | 0 | 0 | 2 429 | 3 743 | 5 075 |
New MS total | 2 041 | 7 627 | 15 332 | 20 596 | 24 329 |
EU enlarged | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Source: Own estimates. |
118
Appendix table 6. Distribution of payments and receipts in EU 15 in 2006 including enlargement costs.
Millions of euro, 1999 prices
Absolute amounts, millions of euro | Euro per | ||||
capita | |||||
Total | Financing of | Allocated | Net position | Net position | |
payments | expenditure | ||||
before UK | |||||
rebate | |||||
Belgium | 2 889 | 247 | 5 368 | 2 433 | 233 |
Denmark | 1 969 | 171 | 1 561 | ||
Germany | 23 852 | 340 | 11 574 | ||
Greece | 1 608 | 136 | 6 357 | 4 725 | 445 |
Spain | 7 085 | 598 | 14 419 | 7 227 | 181 |
France | 16 853 | 1 423 | 12 863 | ||
Ireland | 1 125 | 95 | 2 201 | 1 059 | 279 |
Italy | 13 229 | 1 146 | 10 502 | ||
Luxembourg | 231 | 19 | 1 286 | 1 052 | 2 407 |
Netherlands | 4 708 | 67 | 2 160 | ||
Austria | 2 369 | 34 | 1 424 | ||
Portugal | 1 304 | 110 | 4 189 | 2 865 | 286 |
Finland | 1 473 | 126 | 1 250 | ||
Sweden | 2 730 | 40 | 1 321 | ||
United Kingdom | 17 001 | 7 119 | |||
Source: Own estimates.
Note: See text on why net position is not equal to payments less receipts. Per capita positions estimated on population 2000.
119
120
Terms used
Absorptive capacity: The capacity of a member country to make effective use of funds made available to it from the EU budget. The absorptive capacity will depend among other things on a country’s ability to plan ahead, its institutional capacity for plan implementation and its financial capacity for providing required national
Acquis communautaire: The EU system of rules, regulations and laws, which must be applied by all member countries, including new ones.
Agenda 2000: Action program for the period 2000 – 2006, agreed by the European Council in Berlin, 1999 and later finalized in the Interinstitutional Agreement. Agenda 2000 contains among other things the Financial Perspective for this period.
Allocated expenditure: The part of the EU budget (approx. 90 %) that flows back to the member states in the form of agricultural support, structural funds etc.
Big bang: An enlargement strategy where a large number of candidate countries becomes members at the same time. Presently a big bang accession with 10 countries is expected for 2004.
Candidate countries: 13 countries recognized as official candidates for EU membership through a decision by the European Council at meetings in Luxembourg (1997) and Helsinki (1999). Those countries are the 12 countries with which negotiations are ongoing in 2002 plus Turkey. Other potential member countries are not considered as candidate countries in this context.
121
CAP: The Common Agricultural Policy
CFF: The Common Financial Framework for Negotiations. Proposal from the Commission in January 2002 for financing the enlargement 2004 – 2006.
Commitment appropriations: Appropriations in the EU budget or the Financial Perspective, showing the maximum amount that can be used for an item of expenditure during the budget year or later years.
Convention on the Future of Europe: A specially convened forum for discussing the future of Europe consisting of representatives from governments and the European Parliament. Candidate countries as well as the Civil Society are also represented. The Convention is expected to produce its report in 2003.
Council of the European Union: a.k.a. Council of Ministers or Ministerial Council. The
ECB: The European Central Bank in Frankfurt a/M, Germany.
EU 15: The 15 countries that are members of the EU in 2002.
European Agreements: Agreements between the EU and a number of East European countries on the successive abolition of customs and other barriers to trade. Through the implementation of the European agreements much of the positive trade impact of enlargement on the economies of EU 15 and on candidate countries has been discounted already.
122
European Commission: The 20 commissioners nominated by the member countries for a period of 5 years. The Commission oversees the implementation of agreements and decisions. It has the exclusive right to take initiatives for new legislation.
European Council: The highest
Financial Perspective: The
FYROM: The Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia – the officially recognized designation of that country!
GNI: Gross National Income. A concept replacing the Gross National Product (GNP) as basis for important parts of the Own Resource System.
IGC: The Intergovernmental Conference, technically already in session, but expected to take new,
IIASA: The International Institute for Advanced Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria
Interinstitutional agreement (IIA): Binding agreements between the Parliament, the Council and the Commission on budgetary discipline and the improvement of the budgetary procedure, including the Financial Perspective.
Mode de calcul: The agreed method for calculating the UK rebate.
Net payer: Country, which pays more into the EU budget than the amounts of budget expenditure allocated to it.
Net position: The difference between the payments to the EU budget of a country and the budget expenditure that is allocated back to that country. See appendix 1 for further explanations.
123
Net receiver: Country, which receives larger allocations of expenditure from the EU budget than its contributions to the budget.
Own Resources System: The system for financing the EU budget.
Payment appropriations: Appropriations in the EU budget or the Financial Perspective, showing the amounts that are planned to be paid during a certain year. Payments can be the results of commitments made the same year or earlier.
PPP: Purchasing Power Parities. Gross National Product or Gross National Income data adjusted for differences in purchasing power between countries. Data calculated by the UN, the World Bank, OECD and Eurostat
Regatta: An enlargement strategy where each candidate country becomes a member upon finalization of its negotiation without regard to the status of other candidate countries. Previously the preferred strategy, now in reality abolished.
UNDP: United Nations Development Programme – the UN agency responsible for assistance to third world countries and countries with economies in transition. UNDP publishes each year the Human Development Report, an attempt to give a comprehensive review of the development of human resources and conditions in the member countries.
124
Country abbreviations used in certain tables
B | Belgium |
DK | Denmark |
D | Germany |
Gr | Greece |
ESpain
FFrance
Irl | Ireland |
I | Italy |
Lx | Luxembourg |
NL | the Netherlands |
A | Austria |
P | Portugal |
Fin | Finland |
SE | Sweden |
UK | the United Kingdom |
BU | Bulgaria |
C | Cyprus |
CZ | Czech Republic |
EE | Estonia |
H | Hungary |
Lit | Lithuania |
LLatvia
MMalta
Pl | Poland |
RO | Romania |
n.a. | Slovenia |
Sl | Slovakia |
125
Selected www links
Basic EU treaties and agreements
Basic treaties of the European Union:
The Europe Agreements: http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/pas/europe_agr.htm
New Own Resources Decision: http://europa.eu.int/comm/budget/furtherinfo/index_en.htm#fin ancing
The UK rebate (Method for calculation): http://europa.eu.int/comm/budget/furtherinfo/index_en.htm#fin ancing
The European Commission
Home page:
http://europa.eu.int/comm/index_en.htm
DG enlargement: http://europa.eu.int/comm/dgs/enlargement/index_en.htm
Financial Perspective: http://europa.eu.int/comm/employment_social/esf2000/budget/fi nancial_framework/en.pdf
The Own Resources System: http://europa.eu.int/comm/budget/pdf/agenda2000/finue1998/en/ en.pdf
Enlargement Strategy Paper: http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/report2001/index.htm
126
Common Financial Framework for Negotiations (CFF): http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/docs/index.htm
Allocated expenditure 2000: http://europa.eu.int/comm/budget/agenda2000/reports_en.htm
The Convention on the Future of Europe:
http://europa.eu.int/futurum/congov_en.htm
The Council of the European Commission
The Council:
http://ue.eu.int/en/Info/eurocouncil/index.htm
Some other studies, reports and basic data
(Note: Many of the reports and documents referred to in this study are available on the www. The list of links below contains a selection of sites with good overviews and further links.)
Priset för ett större EU (Karlsson 2001): http://www.regeringen.se/info_rosenbad/departement/finans/eso/
Studies on enlargement assigned by the Commission: http://europa.eu.int/comm/budget/financing/enlargement_en.htm
The Preparity Project (Austria):
http://preparity.wsr.ac.at/
The Countdown Project (Vienna Institute for Comparative Economic Studies):
http://wiiwsv.wsr.ac.at/Countdown/f_searc.html
The Human Development Reports;
http://hdr.undp.org/
127
World Competitiveness Yearbook:
http://www01.imd.ch/wcy/
History of the enlargement process and briefing material: ttp://www.bankaustria.com/index.html(Under tab “Research)
128
References
Dresdner Bank, Germany
1.Herausforderung
European Commission and European Council
2.Agenda 2000 – Financing the European Union,
Commission report on the operation of the own resources system. Brussels, 1998.
3.The Financial Perspective, Annex I and II to the Interinstitutional agreement etc. Document (1999/C 172/01), 1999.
4.Council Decision of 29 September 2000 on the system of the European Communities' own resources, Official Journal of the European Communities, 7.10.2000.
5.The economic impact of enlargement, Enlargement Paper no 4, June 2001.
6.Prospects for agricultural markets
7.Allocation of 2000 EU operating expenditure by Member State. September 2001
8.Progress reports 2001: Strategy Paper - Regular Reports on progress towards accession by each of the candidate countries, 13 November 2001.
9.Information note Common Financial Framework 2004 – 2005 for the Accession Negotiations,
Brussels 30.1.2002.
10.Enlargement and Agriculture: Successfully integrating the new Member States into the CAP, 30.1 2002.
11.First Progress Report on Economic and Social Cohesion, 30.1.2002.
12.The enlargement process and the three
13.
COM (2002) 394 final
129
International Institute for Management Development (IMD), Lausanne, Switzerland
14.The World Competitiveness Yearbook 2002, International Institute for Management Development (IMD), Lausanne, 2002.
United Nations and other international organizations
15.Human Development Report 2001. Making new technologies work for human development,
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) New York, 2001.
16.Population Statistics Online Database. United Nations Population Division, 2002.
17.World Development Indicators 2002. The World Bank Group, 2002.
Other studies
18.Baldwin, R., François, J. and Portes, R., The costs and benefits of eastern enlargement: the impact on the EU and central Europe, Economic Policy, April 1997.
19.Breuss, F., Makroökonomische Auswirkungen der
Teilprojekt 12 des Preparity Project, WIFO, Vienna, April 2001.
20.Dicke, H. and Foders, F., Wirtschaftliche Auswirkungen einer
21.Egger, P. et al., A tale of competition between Eastern
and Southern Europe, WIFO Working Papers 170, Vienna, December 2001.
22.Grevi, G., Beyond the delimitation of competences: implementing subsidiarity, The European Policy Center, Brussels, September 2001.
23.Karlsson, B., Priset för ett större EU – en
24.Keuschnigg, Ch. and Kohler, W., Eastern Enlargement to the EU: Costs and Benefits for the EU Present Member States? The case of Austria, Brussels, 1999.
130
25.Keuschnigg, Ch., Keuschnigg, M. and Kohler, W., Eastern Enlargement to the EU: Costs and Benefits for the EU Present Member States? Germany, Brussels, 1999.
26.Lejour, A.M., de Mooij, R.A. and Nahuis, R., EU enlargement: Economic implications for countries and industries, Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis (CPB), the Hague, September 2001.
27.Parkinson, C.N., Parkinson's Law or The Pursuit of Progress, London, 1958.
28.Pelkmans, J., Gros, D. and Nunez Ferrer, J.,
29.Quaisser, W. and Hall, J., Towards Agenda 2007: Preparing the EU for Eastern Enlargement, Osteuropa Institut, München, February 2002.
30.Quaisser,W., Harmann, M., Hönekopp, E. and Brandmeir, M., Die Osterweiterung der europäischen Union: Konsequenzen für Wohlstand und Beschäftigung in
Europa, Friedrich Ebert Stiftung, March 2000.
31.Schwaag Serger, S., Negotiating CAP – reform in the European Union – Agenda 2000, Swedish Institute for Food and Agricultural Economics, August 2001.
32.Silvis, H.J., van Rijswijk, C.W.J. and de Kleijn, A.J., EU agricultural expenditure for various accession scenarios,
Agricultural Economics Research Institute (LEI), the Hague, April 2001.
33.Smith, A., The return to Europe; The Reintegration of Eastern Europe into the European Economy, School of Slavonic and Eastern European Studies, University of London, Macmillan, 2000.
34.Stankovsky, J., Plasser, F. and Ulram, P., On the Eve of EU Enlargement, Zentrum für angewandte Politikforschung, Wien 1998.
35.Tarschys, D., Bra träffbild, fast utanför tavlan, ESO, Ds 2000:60, October 2000 (Summary in English)
36.Vaittanen, R., Eastern Enlargement of the European Union, Government Institute for Economic Research, Helsinki, May 2000.
131
37.Verbeke, A., Haralambides, H.E., van Klink, A., Veenstra, A.W and Winkelmans, W., Empirical estimation of the final destination of goods imported through the major European gateways, March 1998.
132
List of ESO Reports in English
The Expert Group on Public Finance (ESO) is a Government commission at the Swedish Ministry of Finance. The expert group was established in 1981. All reports since 1993 include a summary (or at least an abstract) in English. A list of all reports published since 1982 and English summaries, when available, can be found at www. regeringen.se/eso. Paper copies can be ordered from the secretariat (+ 46 8 405 1518 or + 46 8 405 1588).
What Price Enlargement? – implications of an expanded EU by Bengt O. Karlsson (Ds 2002:52)
The School’s Need for Resources – a report on the importance of small Classes by Alan B. Krueger & Mikael Lindahl (Ds 2002:12)
Looking ahead through the
Social Security in Sweden – how to reform the system – Jan Bröms, Ingemar Eriksson, Inga Persson and Göran Schubert
Productivity Trends in the Public Sector in Sweden by Richard Murray
The Mobility of Capital – the Swedish tax and expenditure structure in an integrated Europe by Krister Andersson
Social Security in Sweden and other European Countries – three essays by Sven E. Olsson, Hans Hansen and Ingemar Eriksson
133
134