SOU 2000:11
Förord
Finansmarknadsutredningen (Fi 1997:14) tillsattes i oktober 1997 för att utreda den svenska finansiella sektorns internationella konkurrenskraft.
Utredningen har givit ett antal svenska och utländska experter i uppdrag att utarbeta specialstudier till utredningen. Dessa 27 studier har löpande offentliggjorts via utredningens hemsida på internet och redovisas som separata bilagor till betänkandet. Bilagorna har i vissa fall som syfte att ge en sammanfattande bild över forskningsläget på viktiga områden, i andra fall till att djupare analysera vissa centrala frågeställningar. De analyser och slutsatser som läggs fram i dessa bilagor är respektive författares egna och sammanfaller inte nödvän- digtvis med utredningens ståndpunkt.
De 27 specialstudierna finns samlade i fyra volymer. Volym A innehåller fem bilagor som alla granskar finanssektorns betydelse för tillväxten. I volym B:s nio bilagor avhandlas de olika funktioner som finanssektorn har i samhällsekonomin. Volym C:s sju bilagor behandlar en mängd övriga frågor som t.ex. skatter, arbetskraft och regleringar. Volym D innehåller de sex bilagor som har skrivits på engelska.
Stockholm i mars 2000
Bengt Dennis
Särskild utredare
Jonas Niemeyer
Utredningssekreterare
Hans Bäckström
Utredningssekreterare
SOU 2000:11 |
Volym D:5 |
|
|
Innehållsförteckning
Volym A: |
Samhällsekonomisk betydelse |
|
Bilaga 2 |
Den finansiella sektorns samhällsekonomiska |
A:9 |
|
betydelse |
|
|
Nils Lundgren |
|
Bilaga 3 |
Den svenska finansiella sektorns utveckling i |
A:121 |
|
modern tid |
|
|
Johan A. Lybeck |
|
Bilaga 4 |
Det finansiella systemet och den ekonomiska |
A:165 |
|
tillväxten: Svenska erfarenheter |
|
|
Pontus Hansson och Lars Jonung |
|
Bilaga 5 |
Finansiell utveckling och ekonomisk tillväxt: |
A:237 |
|
En problemanalys |
|
|
Carl Johan Åberg |
|
Bilaga 6 |
Fyra perspektiv på finansmarknaderna och |
A:265 |
|
tillväxten – Finansiellt system, makt och |
|
|
ekonomisk tillväxt |
|
|
Lars Niklasson |
|
Volym B: |
Den finansiella sektorns funktioner |
|
Bilaga 7 |
Sparande, investeringar och förmögenhet – |
B:9 |
|
en analys med inriktning på sammansättning |
|
|
och förändring av hushållens sparande och |
|
|
förmögenhet |
|
|
Lennart Berg |
|
Bilaga 8 |
Sparandets nivå och placeringsformer: |
B:69 |
|
Konsekvenser för finansmarknaderna under |
|
|
de kommande 30 åren i Europa |
|
|
Johan A. Lybeck |
|
Volym D:6 |
|
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
|
Bilaga 9 |
Kreditgivningen och den svenska finansiella |
B:121 |
|
sektorns internationella konkurrenskraft |
|
|
Carl Löwenhielm |
|
Bilaga 10 |
Försäkringsmarknaden |
B:159 |
|
Olov Hertzman |
|
Bilaga 11 |
Den svenska bostadsfinansieringsmarknaden |
B:223 |
|
och dess internationella konkurrenskraft |
|
|
Sune Jussil |
|
Bilaga 12 |
Värdepappershandel i Sverige |
B:259 |
|
Jonas Niemeyer |
|
Bilaga 13 |
Clearing och avveckling av svenska värde- |
B:347 |
|
papper |
|
|
Christer Björklund |
|
Bilaga 14 |
Betalningssystemet i Sverige. |
B:423 |
|
Lars Nyberg och Staffan Viotti |
|
Bilaga 15 |
Massbetalningar i Sverige |
B:477 |
|
Hans Bäckström och Gabriela Guibourg |
|
Volym C: |
Övriga bilagor |
|
Bilaga 16 |
Skatternas betydelse för den finansiella sektorns |
C:9 |
|
konkurrenskraft |
|
|
Krister Andersson |
|
Bilaga 17 |
De svenska finansiella marknadernas integration |
C:77 |
|
med utlandet |
|
|
Jens Nystedt |
|
Bilaga 18 |
Finansiella regleringar och konkurrenskraft |
C:129 |
|
Lars Hörngren |
|
Bilaga 19 |
Den finansiella regleringsprocessen |
C:153 |
|
Hans Schedin och Per Håkansson |
|
Bilaga 20 |
Finansiella intermediärers roll i det finansiella |
C:185 |
|
systemet – En översikt av den akademiska |
|
litteraturen Sonja Daltung
SOU 2000:11 |
|
Volym D:7 |
|
|
|
Bilaga 21 |
Arbetskraft och konkurrenskraft i den svenska |
C:233 |
|
finansiella sektorn |
|
|
Sven Jungerhem |
|
Bilaga 22 |
Attitydenkät |
C:283 |
|
Askus |
|
Volym D: |
Supplements in English |
|
Bilaga 23 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and |
D:9 |
|
Growth |
|
|
Raghuram G. Rajan och Luigi Zingales |
|
Bilaga 24 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development |
D:47 |
|
Raghuram G. Rajan och Luigi Zingales |
|
Bilaga 25 |
Is The Financial System Politically |
D:127 |
|
Independent? Perspectives on The Political |
|
|
Economy of Banking and Financial Regulation |
|
|
Randall S. Kroszner |
|
Bilaga 26 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? |
D:161 |
|
Richard J. Herring och Anthony M. Santomero |
|
Bilaga 27 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning in |
D:219 |
|
Banking with Implications for Sweden |
|
|
Arnoud W.A. Boot |
|
Bilaga 28 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and |
D:257 |
|
Productivity in an International Perspective |
|
Lennart Hjalmarsson, Irene Andersson och
Aziz Mlima
SOU 2000:11 |
Volym D:9 |
|
|
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and
Growth
by
Raghuram G. Rajan *
and
Luigi Zingales **
Supplement number 23 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Views, suggestions, and opinions expressed in this study represent the personal views of the authors and not necessarily those of the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
September, 1999
*Joseph L. Gidwitz Professor of Finance, University of Chicago, Financial Management Area, Graduate School of Business. 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, USA.
**Professor of Finance, University of Chicago, Financial Management Area, Graduate School of Business. 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, USA.
Volym D:10 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Table of Contents
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish) ....................................................... |
11 |
Executive Summary .............................................................................. |
12 |
Introduction.......................................................................................... |
13 |
1 Finance development and Growth................................................. |
14 |
1.1Why don’t financial markets and institutions appear
|
instantaneously? ...................................................................... |
15 |
1.2 |
Evidence on Financial Development and Growth ...................... |
18 |
1.3 |
Financial Development and Growth: Details ............................. |
22 |
2 Relationship vs Arm’s length systems ........................................... |
26 |
|
2.1 |
An Example: Credit ................................................................. |
27 |
2.2Do relationship based systems always lead to worse
|
|
investment decisions?............................................................... |
28 |
2.3 |
The distortions in relationship based systems ............................ |
30 |
|
2.4 |
The kinds of assets financed by each system............................. |
33 |
|
2.5 |
Venture Capital: A bridge between two worlds ......................... |
34 |
|
3 |
|
Risk................................................................................................ |
37 |
3.1 |
Why a relationship based system is more risky ......................... |
37 |
|
3.2 |
How to reduce risk in a relationship based system..................... |
38 |
|
4 |
Conclusion: And the winner is ...................................................... |
41 |
|
References............................................................................................. |
43 |
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:11 |
|
|
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish)
Hur påverkar utvecklingen av den finansiella sektorn den industriella tillväxten? Vilken effekt har den på industrins sammansättning och företagens storleksfördelning? Hur skiljer sig olika typer av finansiella system när det gäller sårbarhet i krislägen? Denna studie diskuterar och försöker ge svar på denna typ av frågor, baserat på aktuell forskning.
Den första delen av denna studie fokuserar på de teoretiska och empiriska argumenten varför finansiell utveckling underlättar industriell tillväxt. I den andra delen jämförs två typer av finansiella system: det institutionella, relationsbaserade systemet och det marknadsbaserade ”arm’s
En viktig slutsats är att utvecklingen av ett lands finansiella marknader och finansinstitut dramatiskt kan öka tillväxten i branscher och företag som behöver en stor del extern, långfristig finansiering.
Särskilt intressant är att finansiell utveckling leder till uppkomsten av fler företag inom branscher vars tillgångar till stor del är immateriella som forskning och utveckling. Detta gäller i hög grad för små teknik- baserade företag. Följaktligen underlättar finansiell utveckling struktur- utvecklingen i den industriella sektorn.
Volym D:12 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Executive Summary
How does the development of the financial sector affect industrial growth? What effect does it have on the composition of industry, and the size distribution of firms? What is the relative importance of financial institutions and financial markets, and does it depend on the stage of economic growth? How do financial systems differ in their vulnerability to crisis? This study attempts to provide an answer to these questions based on the current state of empirical research. This is not, however, meant to be a comprehensive survey. Instead, we hope to present our own point of view, bolstered by the available empirical evidence.
The first section of this study will focus on the theoretical rationale and empirical evidence for why financial development aids industrial growth. In the second section, we compare and contrast two types of financial system: the
Our main conclusions are the development of a country’s financial markets and institutions dramatically increases the growth of industries, such as Computers or Pharmaceuticals, that need a lot of external, long- term finance. More interestingly, financial development leads to more firms being born in industries whose assets are largely long term, or in industries where assets are largely intangible ones such as R&D. Thus financial development facilitates the spread of new ideas and leads to the “creative destruction” of the old. By freeing those with ideas from the need for personal wealth to finance them, financial development creates equality of opportunity for everyone in society, something that hitherto has only been a dream.
By increasing the variety and sources of financing, financial development also decreases risk. The sources of financial development, however, are not explored in this study.
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:13 |
|
|
Introduction***
How does the development of the financial sector affect industrial growth? What effect does it have on the composition of industry, and the size distribution of firms? What is the relative importance of financial institutions and financial markets, and does it depend on the stage of economic growth? How do financial systems differ in their vulnerability to crisis? This study attempts to provide an answer to these questions based on the current state of empirical research. This is not, however, meant to be a comprehensive survey. Instead, we hope to present our own point of view, bolstered by the available empirical evidence.
The first section of this study will focus on the theoretical rationale and empirical evidence for why financial development aids industrial growth. In the second section, we compare and contrast two types of financial system: the
*** This study was presented at the Symposium on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Industry organized by the Bank of Sweden Tercentenary Foundation in March 1999. The comments of Erik Berglöf and Jonas Niemeyer are greatly appreciated.
Volym D:14 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
1 Finance development and Growth
There is a long literature debating the impact of finance on growth – dating at least as far back as Schumpeter (1911) – that emphasizes the positive influence of the development of a country's financial sector on the level and the rate of growth of its per capita income. The argument essentially is that the services the financial sector provides – of reallocating capital to the highest value use without substantial risk of loss through moral hazard, adverse selection, or transactions costs – are an important catalyst of economic growth. Early empirical work seemed consistent with this argument. For example, on the basis of data from 35 countries between 1860 and 1963, Goldsmith (1969, p. 48) concludes that ”a rough parallelism can be observed between economic and financial development if periods of several decades are considered” and ”there are even indications in the few countries for which data are available that periods of more rapid economic growth have been accompanied, though not without exception, by an
Nevertheless, studies such as these simply suggest correlation. As Goldsmith puts it ”There is no possibility, however, of establishing with confidence the direction of the causal mechanism, i.e., of deciding whether financial factors were responsible for the acceleration of economic development or whether financial development reflected economic growth whose mainsprings must be sought elsewhere.” While Goldsmith was somewhat pessimistic about the possibility of establishing causation, other economists have expressed downright skepticism that financial development is anything but a sideshow to economic development. Robinson (1952, p. 86) is representative of a school, which seems to believe that institutions follow Say’s law of demand creating its own supply when she claims ”where enterprise leads, finance follows”. Others such as Lucas (1988) argue that the importance of financial development for economic growth has been overemphasized.
The importance of financial markets and institutions in a modern economy is undisputed, and fairly well documented elsewhere, see Levine (1997) and Merton and Bodie (1995), for example. What is more hotly debated is whether financial markets and institutions develop automatically to industrial and individual needs, or whether they take an inordinate time, and special circumstances, to build, and cannot be taken
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:15 |
|
|
for granted. The evidence suggests the latter. Let us first understand why this might be the case, then examine the evidence.
1.1Why don’t financial markets and institutions appear instantaneously?
Clearly, there are large fixed costs and a physical time to build in setting up financial infrastructure. Furthermore, it may be hard for private enterprise to internalize all the gains to doing so, especially if these gains are spread over a long period of time. If there is no
Even after the
More generally, economic theory suggests that a market becomes liquid when, somewhat
Volym D:16 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
the way they trade, and few trades take place. The reasoning is ”if you are willing to sell me this stock and I know you are smart, I wonder what it is you know that I do not, and I am less willing to buy”. The difficulty of providing uninformed investors the confidence to participate in the market when, by their very nature, they will not collect a great deal of information is, in our view, one of the most important impediments to market liquidity.
Investors obtain such confidence, not from a detailed scrutiny of the financial press but from
Financial contracts also take time to perfect. There is a process of trial and error in which institutions initially, and eventually markets, learn the nuances of a financial contract, how to price it, what covenants to build in, how to withstand legal scrutiny, and how to obtain effective enforcement.2 The institutions such as exchanges, audit agencies, custodial services, rating agencies, etc., that help the smooth enforcement of arm’s length contracts take time to set up, and more time to perfect their trade in local conditions.
Financial intermediaries also take time to set up and become effective. As Rajan (1998) argues, institutions intermediate where financial contracts are incomplete, either because contingencies cannot be fully foreseen in the case of innovative transactions, or because the contingencies are too complex to describe up front. The institution uses its reputation to bond itself, and its bargaining power to achieve negotiated outcomes that are superior to those that can be obtained through direct transacting in the market place. A good reputation is crucial for an intermediary because this is what convinces customers to trust it when contracts do not fully protect them, but reputations take time to build, see Kreps and Wilson (1982) and Diamond (1989), for
1See Rajan and Servaes (1997).
2See Rajan (1998).
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:17 |
|
|
example.3 An institution may also be able to bond itself by putting its monetary capital or future rents at stake, but we have already argued that monetary capital may not be available in concentrated form in economies with primitive financial sectors. Moreover, even if available, monetary capital alone may not be particularly effective in providing assurances to customers, see Boot, Greenbaum, and Thakor (1993).
Finally, financial intermediaries take time to build for the same reasons that large industrial firms take time to build, see Rajan and Zingales (1998a). It takes time for employees to learn to work with each other, to build relationships with customers, and to build routines that ensure the smooth functioning of the organization. Moreover, all this learning cannot take place instantaneously, it has to be sequenced, else it could risk overwhelming the command and control capabilities of the organization.
For all these reasons, it is quite possible that financial markets and institutions do not appear on demand, they evolve slowly. Thus the pre- existing state of financial development could have a significant effect on economic growth. Recent evidence seems quite persuasive that this is indeed the case.
1.2Evidence on Financial Development and Growth
The rekindling of interest on the empirical connection between financial development and growth owes much to King and Levine (1993). They
3 In every financial innovation, there are outcomes that are not anticipated up front, and have to be worked out amicably between intermediary and client. This is where the intermediary's reputation plays a part. Some intermediaries develop reputations for being
Volym D:18 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
study 80 countries over the period
While the evidence in this paper sheds additional light, it does not lay to rest all doubts about causality. The skeptic could still offer a number of arguments.
First, both financial development and growth could be driven by a common omitted variable such as the propensity of households in the economy to save. Since endogenous savings (in certain macroeconomic models) affects the long run growth rate of the economy, it may not be surprising that growth and initial financial development are correlated. This argument is also hard to refute with simple
Second, there is a potential problem of anticipation. Financial development – typically measured by the level of credit and the size of the stock market – may predict economic growth simply because financial markets anticipate future growth; the stock market capitalizes the present value of growth opportunities, while financial institutions lend more if they think sectors will grow. Thus financial development may simply be a leading indicator rather than a causal factor.4
One way to deal with the first problem, that of omitted variables, is to keep effects other than financial development constant. An ingenious paper by Jayaratne and Strahan (1996) does precisely this. Between
4 Levine and Zervos (1998) attempt to deal with this by using stock market liquidity rather than market capitalization as a measure of financial development. Market expectations could also be built into liquidity, see Shleifer and Vishny (1992), though to a much lesser extent than into market capitalization.
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:19 |
|
|
1972 and 1991, a number of states in the United States did away with regulations preventing banks from opening multiple branches within the state. The authors argue that
Of course, one could ask again whether financial sector reform leads to economic growth, or vice versa. Did states liberalize anticipating greater need for financing because of economic growth? Jayaratne and Strahan argue that if this was the case, the volume of bank lending should have exploded after
Jayaratne and Strahan essentially follow a difference in differences approach by asking what happens in a state after
Their rationale is a theoretical one. They argue that the way to make progress on causality is to focus on the details of the theoretical mechanisms through which financial development affects economic growth and empirically document their working. Specifically, theorists argue that financial markets and institutions help a firm overcome problems of moral hazard and adverse selection, thus reducing the firm's cost of raising money from outsiders. So financial development should disproportionately help firms (or industries) typically dependent on external finance for their growth. Such a finding, they argue, could be the ‘smoking gun’ in the debate about causality. There are two virtues to this simple test. First, it looks for evidence of a specific mechanism by which finance affects growth, thus providing a stronger test of causality. Second, it can correct for fixed country (and industry) effects. As a result, the empirical test is less dependent on a specific macroeconomic model of growth.
Rajan and Zingales construct the test as follows. They identify an industry's need for external finance (the difference between investments and cash generated from operations) from data on U.S. firms. Under the
Volym D:20 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
assumption that capital markets in the United States, especially for the large listed firms they analyze, are relatively frictionless, this method allows them to identify an industry's technological demand for external financing. Under the further assumption that such a technological demand carries over to other countries, they examine whether industries that are more dependent on external financing grow relatively faster in countries that, a priori, are more financially developed.
In contrast to prior studies that have used measures of financial development that are based on actual financing – such as the quantity of domestic credit or the size of the stock market – Rajan and Zingales use the accounting standards in that particular country. This has the advantage of measuring the potential of the financial infrastructure rather than its past use.
Their hypothesis would imply that, ceteris paribus, an industry such as Drugs and Pharmaceuticals, which requires a lot of external funding, should develop relatively faster than Tobacco, which requires little external finance, in countries that are more financially developed. Consider, for instance, Malaysia, Korea, and Chile, which are moderate- income
5
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:21 |
|
|
Rajan and Zingales do two additional tests that suggest causality from finance to economic growth. First, they instrument indicators of financial development with measures of the origin's of a country's legal system (whether British, French, German or Scandinavian as classified by La Porta et al., 1998), and with the efficiency of the country's judicial system. These instruments, especially the former, are likely to be pre- determined, and do not reflect development in anticipation of economic growth. The results persist after instrumenting. Second, Rajan and Zingales drop industries that were large at the beginning of the period and are more likely to have been responsible for the country's financial development. They find that industries that are small at the beginning of the period and financially dependent grow faster in countries that are more financially developed than do less dependent industries. This finding in a sample that is unlikely to be responsible for the state of development of the financial markets, suggests that financial development does indeed facilitate growth, and is not simply correlated with it.
Rajan and Zingales' findings indicate that financial markets and institutions may develop to meet the needs of one set of industries, but then facilitate the growth of another younger group of industries, consistent with Chandler's (1977) description of the evolution of financial infrastructure in the United States in the nineteenth century. Goldsmith (1985, p. 2) based on a study of the
1.3Financial Development and Growth: Details
1.3.1The Kinds of Firms that are Financed
There is now a growing body of work that documents in greater detail the kinds of firms in the modern economy that financial development helps. Carlin and Mayer (1998) present an extremely interesting set of correlations. Using data from 27 industries in 20 OECD countries over the period 1970 to 1995, they find that industries funding a lot of investment with equity tend to grow faster, and do more R&D, in
Volym D:22 Supplement 23 SOU 2000:11
countries that have better accounting standards. They also find that industries where workers have high skill levels tend to grow faster and do more R&D in countries with better accounting standards.6 Interestingly, equity financed industries undertake less fixed capital formation in countries with better accounting standards.
In direct contrast to equity financed industries, bank debt financed industries tend to grow more slowly in countries that are more financially developed and also tend to undertake less R&D. Finally, in contrast to what happens in developed countries, bank dependent industries in countries with low GDP grow faster as the banking system develops but are relatively unaffected by improvements in accounting standards.
What do we make of these findings? Once we think of fixed capital as collateral, then interpretation becomes much easier. Typically, equity financed industries tend to have few hard assets, and substantial intangible assets such as growth opportunities, see Myers (1977). In economies with underdeveloped financial markets and institutions, collateral is essential to obtain outside financing. Thus we would expect industries that would optimally use few hard assets if finance were easy to come by, to use more of them in countries with underdeveloped financial systems. But as accounting standards and credit markets develop, equity financed industries would tend to use less fixed capital, as the evidence suggests. In other words, the intangible assets that they typically possess in abundance become easier to finance, and they do not have to distort asset holdings towards fixed capital.
Carlin and Mayer's other findings are also consistent with the above interpretation. Because the intangible assets in equity financed firms become easier to finance as the financial system develops (where development is measured as better accounting standards, or more bank credit), the industry grows faster, and can finance more R&D – one of the biggest sources of intangible assets. Similarly, a highly skilled workforce is an important intangible asset, and the finding that industries with highly skilled workers tend to grow more and do more R&D as financial markets develop corroborates our interpretation. Finally, industries dependent on bank finance in Japan (which is where Carlin and Mayer measure bank dependence) tend to be physical capital
6 Following Rajan and Zingales (1998), Carlin and Mayer proxy for an industry's dependence on equity finance by the amount of equity that industry uses to finance investment in the United States. They measure the industry's dependence on bank finance by how much that industry uses in Japan, and they measure the industry's use of skilled workers based on how many workers in that industry in Germany are not classified as unskilled.
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:23 |
|
|
intensive,
In sum, it appears that industries can raise finance more easily as the financial system develops because physical collateral becomes less important, while intangible assets and future cash flows can be financed.
1.3.2The Effects of Development of Firm Size and Birth
Industry growth can be decomposed into the growth in the number of firms and the growth in the average size of firms. As Rajan and Zingales (1998b) find, 2/3rd of industrial growth over the 1980s in their sample of 43 countries comes from the growth in the average size of establishments, 1/3rd from the growth in the number of establishments. But in their regressions, they find financial development has almost twice the economic effect on the latter than on the former. So the effect of financial development on both the size and the birth of firms seems important.
In a study of 15 OECD countries, Kumar, Rajan and Zingales (1999) find that industries dependent on external finance tend to have smaller firms on average, as do countries with low levels of financial development. Moreover, financially dependent industries tend to have larger firms in countries with
By constraining firms from growing to their full potential, the lack of financial development could have serious effects. Firms in financially underdeveloped countries could be inefficiently small, or left unable to undertake the necessary takeovers that would allow them to compete in a increasingly
Volym D:24 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
The absence of financial development could also prevent the emergence of new ideas. When firms start out, many of their assets are intangible ideas and project opportunities. These ideas typically do not respect the status quo, and often make possible Schumpeterian ”waves of creative destruction”. By allowing intangible assets to be financed, financial development facilitates innovation and change.
We have more evidence in favor of this hypothesis. Kukies (in progress) finds that the growth in the number of establishments (though not the growth in average firm size) is relatively higher for industries that do a lot of R&D, and for industries that have a higher portion of long term assets, in countries where financial markets are more developed. This indicates that it is very hard for emergent firms to finance intangible or illiquid assets without financial market development.
There are also some puzzling pieces of evidence. Some developed countries have both good accounting standards (which, across countries, is strongly positively correlated with stock market capitalization) and a high proportion of bank lending, but in general these countries are exceptions. In fact, Carlin and Mayer find the raw correlation between the two measures of financial development to be negative in their sample. Why is it that bank credit tapers off as stock markets develop?
That economies seem to emphasize either institutions or markets has led economists to classify financial systems as relationship based (or bank dominated) and arm’s length (or market based). What distinguishes these two types of systems? Moreover, do they have different effects when countries are at different stages of growth? Could this explain why bank dependent industries grow faster in bank dominated economies only when the economies are relatively
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:25 |
|
|
2Relationship vs Arm’s length systems
Let us begin with a sketch of the salient features of these two kinds of systems. Like all sketches, this one has elements of caricature, but this is the price we have to pay to avoid being distracted by the details.
A financial system has two primary goals: to channel resources to their most productive uses and to ensure that an adequate portion of the return flows to the financier. The latter is, of course, crucial to the former. Without the prospect of an adequate return, funds will not be made available for investment.
Even when it is clear that the social returns from a project are high, it is not necessary that the financier will be able to appropriate an adequate return. The borrower may take actions that improve its private return at the expense of the financier’s return. This is the problem of moral hazard. Alternatively, the financier may not be able to distinguish between honest entrepreneurs and knaves, and this problem of adverse selection may again prevent the financier from recovering the amount invested. What is really needed is that the financier have both information, as well as the ability to act on that information.
Relationship based systems ensure a return to the financier by granting her some power over the firm being financed. The sources of power can be varied. It may be purely financial, stemming from the financier’s monopoly control over supply of funds to the firm because of its
Contrast this with the
Volym D:26 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
relationships matter less and the market becomes a more important medium for directing/governing the terms of transactions.
An important distinction between these two systems is their different degree of reliance on legal enforcement. Relationship based systems can survive in environments where laws are poorly drafted and contracts not enforced. The relationship is largely
Another distinction between the two systems is the relative importance of transparency.
2.1An Example: Credit
Before going further, let us consider the example of a transaction – the extension of credit – in each of the two systems. In a relationship based system, a bank will have close ties with a potential borrowing firm, perhaps because of frequent past contacts or because of ownership links. In assessing the borrowing needs of the firm and its ability to pay interest and principal, the bank will consider not only the firm's current
7See La Porta, et al. (1997).
8In Joel Seligman, The Transformation of Wall Street, Northeastern University Press, Boston 1995, p. 42.
9For example, the bank may refuse to extend a blanket guarantee to the firm’s other creditors, refuse to provide new financing or even take a piece of it, etc.
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:27 |
|
|
The interest rate charged will be repeatedly negotiated over time, and may not have a direct relationship to the intrinsic risk of the project.
In an
Limitations on competition in a relationship system do not just give the financier power, but also strengthen his incentive to
The absence of competition and disclosure in a relationship based system imply that there are really no price signals to guide decisions. Unlike an
2.2Do relationship based systems always lead to worse investment decisions?
But is this necessarily a bad thing? Are lending and investment decisions always inefficient if the cost of funds differs from their true cost? Are there no redeeming features of a relationship based system? The answer to all these questions is no. In the real world with all its ”imperfections,”
10 See Hoshi, et al. (1990a).
Volym D:28 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
an imperfect cost of funds can sometimes produce the right investment decisions.
For instance, consider our previous example of a firm in distress. Taking into consideration all the value that the firm adds to society – to workers, customers, and local governments as well as shareholders – the company may be worth saving. But, in the short run, the true cost of funding may far exceed what the firm can pay without creating further investment distortions.11 And in the competitive
Petersen and Rajan (1995) provide evidence of the existence of such relationship lending practices even in the U.S. In examining bank loans to small businesses in different banking ”markets” throughout the U.S., 12 their study finds that in ”concentrated” markets (those where most of the lending is done by a handful of banks) – which are likely to be more
The study also finds that the interest rates charged to younger firms are, on average, lower in concentrated markets than in competitive markets, with the effect reversing for older firms. This suggests that banks in concentrated markets can offer more credit on economic terms because their relationships allow ”intertemporal
11For example, too high an interest rate could lead the firm to take riskier, negative NPV, projects, see Jensen and Meckling (1976).
12The idea of distinct banking markets makes sense in this case because small firms rarely do business with a bank outside their local banking market; the median borrower in the above cited study is only two miles from its bank.
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:29 |
|
|
pay. Such subsidies, as suggested earlier, would not be possible in more competitive markets.
Clearly, it is this kind of ability to ”internalize joint surplus” – that is, to trade off
2.3The distortions in relationship based systems
2.3.1Poor price signals
Perhaps most important, the relationship based system does not pay much attention to market or price signals. And this indifference to price signals becomes
This is not to say that the arm’s length system is perfect in the allocation of resources. Because outsiders have little power, management can indulge itself far more in
Evidence of this unwillingness to respond to market signals was provided by a 1991 study by Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein.14 The study looked at a sample of Japanese firms in the late 1970s to mid 1980s that had close ties to banks and compared their investment
13 If anything, managerial
extensively and absorb free cash flows from successful firms. 14 Hoshi, et al (1991).
Volym D:30 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
behavior with a sample that had no such ties. The investments of firms that had no bank tie were very sensitive to the cash flow the firms generated from operations; when operating cash flows decreased sharply, so did investment spending – and vice versa. By contrast, the investments of firms with strong ties to the banks were significantly less sensitive to the firms' operating cash flow.
As suggested earlier, one possible interpretation of these findings is that banking relationships make it easier for firms to obtain external funding for
Weinstein and Yafeh (1998) suggest that such market skepticism was warranted. For while Japanese firms with close bank ties may have had greater access to funds when their operating cash flows declined, such access did not enable them to achieve higher profits or growth rates than their peers.
Peek and Rosengren (1998) provide additional evidence that relationships can distort the allocation of funds. In the early 1990s, Japanese banks increased their lending to the U.S. commercial real estate market. At their peak in 1992, the U.S. subsidiaries of Japanese banks accounted for one fifth of all commercial real estate loans held in the U.S. banking sector. Then, in response to a severe decline in real estate prices in Japan, the Japanese banks cut back their lending in the U.S. even as U.S. prices were rising (and lending by
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:31 |
|
|
In sum, one downside of a relationship based system is that price signals are obscured. The consequence could be a widespread and costly misallocation of resources.
By contrast, there is a virtuous circle at work in
2.3.2Market Power
Another consequence of prices being obscured in a relationship based system is that the financier’s information is largely private especially when the projects being financed consist of intangible assets such as intellectual property. Since the creation of intellectual assets requires substantial endeavor on the part of management, the rent sharing entailed in a relationship system can depress management effort, making innovation, especially of the entrepreneurial kind in high technology industries, a rare commodity.
2.3.3Illiquidity
Because information is so concentrated in a relationship based system, financial assets become very illiquid. Since the relationship is specific to the intermediary and borrower, the intermediary becomes indispensable to collecting on loans. As a result, the intermediary can extract sizeable rents from investors also, see Diamond and Rajan (1998), because they need the intermediary’s skills to realize the value of the intermediary’s loan portfolio. Anticipating these rents, investors will charge the intermediary a high cost of capital. Moreover, the financial asset will be illiquid in the sense that it will trade in the market for true value (the amount that can be collected from borrowers) less the rent accruing to the intermediary because of its indispensable relationship specific skills. The illiquidity of financial assets makes it very costly for the financial system if the intermediary gets into trouble since more liquid outsiders cannot take over its assets easily.
Volym D:32 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
2.4The kinds of assets financed by each system
All this then suggests why pure relationship based systems tend to have a comparative advantage in financing physical asset intensive industries rather than high technology R&D based industries. For one, physical capital intensive industries are typically more traditional and well understood. As a result, the absence of market signals about their profitability is less likely to be a problem in making investment decisions. Second, because they are well understood, it is unlikely that a large amount of rents will accrue to the financing intermediary. Moreover, the borrower has the collateral to entice fresh lenders if the existing one proves demanding. Finally, since loans are well collateralized by physical assets, they are liquid, so the concentration of information is less important a barrier for the intermediary to finance its assets.
Conversely, arm's length systems will have a comparative advantage financing industries with intangible assets, hence Carlin and Mayer’s finding that equity- and
An intriguing recent study fortifies our view that relationship based systems are more capable of financing projects where the ratio of tangible to intangible assets is large. Houston and James (1995) study the financing arrangements of 250 public firms in the United States. They find that firms with relationships to single banks tend to use less bank debt in proportion to total debt as their market to book ratio (a measure of the ratio of intangible to tangible assets) increases. By contrast, when firms have relationships with multiple banks, the ones with higher market to book ratios tend to use more bank debt in proportion to total debt. This suggests that firms tend to avoid becoming dependent on a single bank when they have high market to book ratios, perhaps because they fear the bank may have too much power to extract rents and direct strategies, or because the bank itself will find the asset too illiquid.
By contrast, when the firm has multiple banking relationships (effectively an arm’s length system), no single bank has too much power. Since public markets can obtain information about the firm from multiple sources, the cost of borrowing more from banks to fund is small relative to the insurance and advice provided by relationships. Thus the revealed preference of firms, in an environment where they can choose the relationship structure that benefits them most, gives us a sense of when a relationship is onerous and when it is not.
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:33 |
|
|
This study also suggests the answer to an apparent contradiction. If relationships are inimical to the financing of skill based and high technology industries, then why is it that venture capital, which seems the quintessential form of relationship financing, is so important in their financing even in the most advanced arm’s length systems. We believe that the conditions under which venture capital arises ensure that the worst problems of the relationship system are tempered by the close proximity of the arm’s length system. The error leading to the apparent contradiction is to view venture capital as purely a form of relationship financing. In fact, it seems an ideal bridge between relationship and arm’s length financing, combining the best of both worlds.
2.5Venture Capital: A bridge between two worlds
Relationship based finance, as we have seen, has the virtue that the financier has substantial control over the financed, and is able to guide the borrower’s moves, as well as thwart any malfeasance. How can the venture capitalist bring these virtues to financing high technology without inflicting the costs associated with relationship financing?
In our view, the role of the venture capitalist is to reduce the illiquidity of the financed firm – which is the source of many of the ills of the relationship system – and the existence of a vibrant arm’s length market is crucial for him to perform his role. His constant endeavor after financing the firm initially is to prepare to exit. He does this by making the firm’s management and control processes standardized and bureaucratic, transparent, and easy for arm’s length investors to take over. The venture capitalist also moves the firm from being an organization dependent on the founder to an organization capable of being run by professional managers. This again makes the firm easier for arm’s length investors to control since managers are easier to replace than founders.15
Why does the venture capitalist not simply hold on to his stake in the firm and extract rents? The answer is that he obtains much greater returns from taking the firm public. The growth opportunities of the typical successful venture capital financed firm are so high that the venture capitalist would not be able to finance them in entirety without severely rationing his other ventures. As a result, unless the venture
15 For a theoretical analysis of the control role of venture capital, see Berglöf (1994), for an empirical analysis, see Gompers (1995).
Volym D:34 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
capitalist makes the firm easy for outsiders to finance – by establishing standardized management procedures and disclosure which make it easy for outsiders to understand, and exert control over, the firm – many of the growth opportunities the firm has access to will lapse. By contrast, if the venture capitalist does prepare the firm for outside control, and takes the firm public in an Initial Public Offering, the Net Present Value of future growth opportunities will be embedded in the stock price, and the venture capitalist will be amply rewarded for his endeavor through his stock holding. The incentives for the venture capitalist are clear, and it is obvious that the presence of an efficient and liquid stock market that can anticipate the firm’s future opportunities is crucial. 16
Moreover, venture capital partnerships are structured with a limited life, which again serves as a commitment to let go of the firm. The need to exit via the market ensures that prices eventually do matter and discipline the investments that take place. Thus the incentives for innovation, the liquidity, and the price discipline provided by the market are combined through the venture capitalist with many of the benefits of control and long horizons provided by the relationship based system.17
A number of countries have tried to seed the process of venture capital, with the hope of emulating the successes of Silicon Valley. Often, this takes the form of making available a fund targeted at high- tech industries, presumably based on the idea that the government can bear risks that private investors may be reluctant to bear. The discussion above points to three other barriers to the emergence of venture capital, all of which may be more important than risk aversion in explaining why private capital does not come forth. First, there should exist industries with a sufficiently high potential growth rate to make venture capital effective – high tech, by itself, is not enough. Second, venture capitalists should possess the rare combination of financial expertise in discerning viable projects from
16It may not be necessary for the market to be domestic. If domestic accounting practices and corporate governance are adequate, it may be possible for a foreign market to serve as the liquid exit market for venture capitalists. A case in point is Israeli high tech firms that have been choosing the NASDAQ for their Initial Public Offerings. However, Israel may be a special case.
17It is interesting that German banks were performing a similar role to venture capital around the turn of the century, and German public markets were vibrant, Calomiris (1994). It would be useful to understand what changed.
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:35 |
|
|
equity market should exist which is capable of reflecting the venture capitalist’s contribution in the firm stock price when the firm is taken public (see Black and Gilson (1998) for an early exposition on the market being an essential exit route for venture capitalists). Simply putting traditional bankers in charge of a pool of funds targeted at high tech firms without giving them hands on experience in an existing venture market, and without creating a vibrant equity market for new issues, will most likely doom official venture capital efforts to failure.
In sum, relationship based systems can work very well in the early stages of industrialization where the industries to be financed are physical asset intensive, where the legal system is ineffective, and where skill based or idea based industries are of limited import. But as economies develop and focus more on knowledge intensive industries as engines for growth, a hybrid is perhaps more effective. There is then the need to improve transparency, judicial efficiency, and mechanisms for speedy resolution of financial distress so that arm’s length markets can function effectively and aid the process of economic growth.
Volym D:36 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
3 Risk
In the current economic situation where America is ascendant while Japan is mired in bad loans, it is tempting to conclude that the arm’s length system dominates other forms. We believe that is a misreading of the evidence. The United States does not have a purely arm’s length system, and even so, to conclude that the system is optimal is probably as wrong as the conclusion in the late 1980s that the Japanese relationship based system was worthy of emulation in its entirety. Nevertheless, if there is one thing the arm’s length can do better than the relationship system, it is to bear and manage
3.1Why a relationship based system is more risky
We have already argued that assets financed by relationship based systems tend to be illiquid since there is little transparency and disclosure. Diamond and Rajan (1998) argue that intermediaries can finance such assets at low cost only by issuing a high proportion of demandable claims. Intuitively, intermediaries in relationship based systems finance assets that only they understand. The only reason that they do not absorb a massive amount of rents as a result of their monopoly position is because they credibly commit to pay out collections to depositors. This requires them to issue hard claims – the hardest being demandable claims subject to runs. Thus in the natural course of financing illiquid relationship assets, financial intermediaries have to take on financial risk.
Risk can be mitigated if the intermediation system is well capitalized because capital acts as a buffer. Given the low levels of private capital in emerging economies, historically, the government has created capital for intermediaries by keeping the rates intermediaries pay investors low. This has become infeasible as deregulation and competition has given investors more choice. Consequently, the task of averting the collapse of the system of intermediation in the face of severe macroeconomic volatility has shifted directly to the government. Governments have had to absorb risk by promising the intermediation system capital, implicitly
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:37 |
|
|
or explicitly, in case the system is in danger. But the promise of such contingent capital carries with it the risk that intermediaries will collectively attempt to game the system through moral hazard.
In other words, illiquid assets can only be financed by financially fragile intermediaries, who then impose risk on the system. To reduce risk, the government has to promise intermediaries contingent capital, which in turn causes them to bet on the same risks such as real estate or emerging market lending, knowing fully well that they will be rescued if only they sink together.
Moreover, once a relationship based system suffers a severe shock that the government is not able to counter, the flow of credit can collapse quickly. This is because, first, there is a lot of specific knowledge and trust embedded in relationships that cannot be transferred to wealthy unaffected outsiders. The illiquidity of the relationships prevents a quick takeover by, say, foreigners. Second, since property rights are not well established in relationships, it becomes hard to separate healthy unaffected parties from the walking dead. The inefficiency of the judicial system does not help. As a result, the relationship based system tends to share the consequences of an adverse shock somewhat indiscriminately. So, it is no wonder that outside capital does not flow in until the system essentially sorts itself out.
Contrast this with the arm’s length system where the accent is on providing small investors the confidence to invest directly in firms. Clearly, such a system is better able to withstand shock, first, because the healthy can be distinguished from the terminally ill after a shock and can be dealt with differently and, second, because unaffected outsiders have the ability to invest and revive the system, as they obtain confidence from the very same channels that inspire confidence in small investors.18
3.2How to reduce risk in a relationship based system
We have argued that elements of both relationships and arm’s length financing are needed in the modern economy. Moreover, a combination of both may serve to reduce the risk of a financial meltdown. But what if
18 This is not to say that markets do not seize up on particular firms. In fact, many banks advertise their relationship business as a port of safe haven for firms affected by a market storm. Nevertheless, we think it highly unusual for all world markets to be irrationally down on an entire country.
Volym D:38 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
the economy is more primitive so that arm’s length financing is not possible?
As Levine (1999) shows, the growth of the intermediary sector is correlated with an improvement in creditor rights and contract enforcement. Thus the reliance on relationships, even within the intermediated sector, can diminish as contracting improve. But what if a country urgently needs to reduce risk? Perhaps the quickest, but politically most difficult, way of reducing the aggregate risk of the intermediated sector is to allow massive entry of foreign intermediaries. Using bank level data across a broad
What could explain these findings? Clearly, foreign banks may influence local supervisory or risk management practices, as also local bank efficiency. But they could have other spillover effects. Specifically, foreign banks, because of their vast outside resources, will survive a local crisis. Not only does this give them little incentive to herd on the same risks as local banks, it also gives the government confidence that a financial crisis will not result in a total meltdown. As a result, the government will be less eager to bail out failed local banks. Moreover, the foreign banks offer an avenue for foreign investors to invest in the local economy despite the absence of safeguards necessary for arm’s length investing, thus shortening the duration of a purely financial crisis. But taken together, perhaps the most salutary effect is on domestic bank incentives. Knowing that the government will be more reluctant to bail them out, they will be more careful about herding on certain systematic risks. Of course, foreign banks come with their problems including the fact that they are impervious to domestic political compulsions (often a blessing) and they are hard for domestic central banks to control (ditto).
We do not believe that emerging markets should unquestioningly open their doors to all forms of foreign capital. In the absence of well developed markets or foreign intermediaries, foreign capital inflows other than foreign direct investment have to be intermediated into the domestic economy by the domestic banking system. Since foreign capital demands substantial safeguards such as implicit or explicit seniority, and a short maturity, in return for putting money in a relatively opaque system, this simply adds another dimension of risk to the domestic banking system. If inflows are large, there is the risk of a rational large scale search for the exits, if the system is shocked (for example, by
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:39 |
|
|
devaluation). Rajan and Zingales (1998c) and Diamond and Rajan (1999) explain why such inflows could have contributed to the Asian financial crisis. Thus in opening up, countries should distinguish between foreign intermediaries that open domestic branches, develop local expertise, are well tied into the system, and thus serve to stabilize it, and foreign portfolio inflows that rely on domestic intermediaries and could overload the system.
Volym D:40 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
4 Conclusion: And the winner is…
We started this study by documenting that there does seem to be a causal relationship between financial development and economic growth. Furthermore, financial development seems to particularly help the financing of firms that typically do not get institutional credit because they lack physical collateral. This lead us to a comparative analysis of relationship based banking systems and arm’s length market based systems. We concluded that for the kinds of industries that are now engines of world growth, a hybrid is probably best, though not all the best properties of each system survive in the hybrid. Finally, we argue that the developed legal infrastructure necessary to sustain a large banking system or arm’s length markets also tends to diminish risk.
From a policy perspective, it would appear that a country intent on economic development should fix its financial plumbing – specifically its accounting and disclosure system and its legal and bankruptcy codes. In a companion study, we will argue that political forces, more than anything else, prevent the emergence of financial systems that are appropriate for economic activity. On the one hand, this is good news because it suggests that wholesale systemic change – in fundamental legal infrastructure, for example – is not needed to achieve financial development. On the other, this is bad news because political forces are hard to overcome. We believe, however, that the natural increase in competition between firms in different nations will force political forces to eventually give way.
Finally, it is tempting to anoint a specific country as having the best financial system. We want to refrain from this. One reason is that we have so much to learn about how financial systems work, even though we have come a long way in recent years. But perhaps a more important reason is that even a cursory study of a sample of the richest countries in the world will reveal a variety of financial systems. Clearly, there are many paths to gold. While there are signs that indicate convergence to a hybrid (the United States using venture capital and Germany opening the New Market), these are far from conclusive. Moreover, many of the stylized facts about the effects of particular systems – such as the “fact” that bank oriented economies tend to have firms with more debt – are illusory when examined more closely, see Rajan and Zingales (1995). Therefore, we will not go beyond the facts and the interpretations
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:41 |
|
|
detailed above, and like all good academics, leave further speculation to future research.
Volym D:42 Supplement 23 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
References
Berglöf, E., (1994), ”A control theory of venture capital finance”,
Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 10,
Capital Markets: Banks vs Stock Markets”, Journal of Financial Economics 47, No. 3,
Boot, A., S. Greenbaum, and A. Thakor, (1993), ”Reputation and Discretion in Financial Contracting”, American Economic Review 83,
Calomiris, C., (1994), ”The Costs of Rejecting Universal Banking: American Finance in the German Mirror,
Carlin, W., and C. Mayer, (1998), ”Finance, Investment and growth”, mimeo, University College, London.
Chandler, A., (1977), ”The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business”, Harvard University Press: Cambridge MA.
Diamond, D.W., (1989), ”Reputation Acquisition in Debt markets”,
Journal of Political Economy, 98,
Diamond, D.W., and R. Rajan, (1998), ”Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation and Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking”, mimeo, University of Chicago.
Diamond, D.W., and R. Rajan, (1999), ”A Theory of Bank Capital”, mimeo, University of Chicago.
Goldsmith, R., (1969), Financial Structure and Development, Yale University Press, New Haven.
Goldsmith, R., (1985), Comparative National Balance Sheets, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Gompers, P., (1995), ”Optimal Investment, monitoring, and the staging of venture capital”, Journal of Financial Economics, 50,
Houston, J. and C. James, (1996), ”Bank Information M onopolies and the Mix of Private and Public debt Claims”, Journal of Finance, vol. 51,
SOU 2000:11 Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:43
Hoshi, T., A. Kashyap, and D. Scharfstein, (1990a), ”The Role of Banks in Reducing the Costs of Financial Distress in Japan”,
Journal of Financial Economics, 27,
Hoshi, T., A. Kashyap, and D. Scharfstein, (1990b), ”Bank monitoring and investment: evidence from the changing structure of Japanese corporate banking relationships”, in R. Glenn Hubbard ed.:
Asymmetric Information, Corporate Finance and Investment, (University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL).
Hoshi, T., A. Kashyap, and D. Scharfstein, (1991), ”Corporate Structure, Liquidity, and Investment: Evidence from Japanese Panel Data”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 27,
Jayaratne, J. and P. E. Strahan, (1996), ”The
Jensen, M., and W. Meckling, (1976), ”Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Capital Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 3,
King, R. and R. Levine, (1993), ”Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. CVIII, No. 3,
Kreps, D. and R. Wilson, (1982), ”Reputation and Imperfect Competition”, Journal of Economic Theory, 27,
Kukies, J. (in progress), CRSP paper, University of Chicago.
Kumar, K., R. Rajan and L. Zingales, (1999), ”What are the determinants of firm size?”, mimeo, University of Chicago.
La Porta, R., F. Lopez de Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, (1997), ”The Legal Determinants of External Finance”, Journal of Finance, 52.
La Porta, R., F. Lopez de Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, (1998), ”Law and Finance”, Journal of Political Economy, 106,
Levine, R., (1997), ”Financial development and Ec onomic Growth: Views and Agenda”, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 35,
Levine, R., (1999), ”Law, Finance and Ec onomic Growth”, forthcoming,
Journal of Financial Intermediation.
Levine, R. and S. Zervos, (1998), ”Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth”, American Economic review, vol. 88, No. 3,
Lucas, R. E., (1988), ”On the Mechanics of Ec onomic Development”,
Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1),
Volym D:44 Supplement 23 SOU 2000:11
Merton, R.C. and Z. Bodie, (1995), ”A conceptual framework for analyzing the financial environement”, in The Global Financial System: A functional Perspective, Dwight Crane ed., Boston MA, Harvard Business School Press.
Myers, S., (1977), ”The determinants of corporate borrowing”, Journal of Financial Economics, 5,
Peach, W. N., (1941), The Security Affiliates of National Banks, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.
Peek, J., and E. Rosengren, (1998), ”The International Transmission of Financial Shocks: The Case of Japan”, American Economic Review, 87,
Petersen, M. and R. Rajan, (1995), ”The Effect of Credit Market Competition on Lending Relationships”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 110,
Rajan, R., (1998), ”The Past and Future of Commercial Banking Viewed through an Incomplete Contract Lens”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 30: (3),
Rajan, R. and H. Servaes, (1997), ”Analyst Following of Initial Public Offerings”, Journal of Finance, vol. 52, 2,
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, (1995), ”Is There an Optimal Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data”, Journal of Finance, vol. 50,
Rajan R. and L. Zingales, (1998a), ”The Firm as a Dedicated Hierarchy”, mimeo, University of Chicago.
Rajan R. and L. Zingales, (1998b), ”Financial Dependence and Growth”, American Economic Review, vol. 88,
Rajan R. and L. Zingales, (1998c), ”Which Capitalism? Lessons from the East Asian Crisis”, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Fall 1998, vol. 11, No. 3,
Rajan, Raghuram and Luigi Zingales, (2000), ”Politics, Law, and Financial Development”, Supplement No. 24 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Robinson, J., (1952), ”The Generalization of the General Theory”, in The Rate of Interest and Other Essays, London, Macmillan,
Schumpeter, J. A., (1911), A Theory of Economic Development, Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA.
Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny, (1992), Liquidation value and debt capacity: A market equilibrium approach, Journal of Finance, 47,
SOU 2000:11 |
Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth Volym D:45 |
|
|
Weinstein, D. and Y. Yafeh, (1998), ”On the Costs of a Bank Centered Financial System: Evidence from the Changing Main Bank Relations in Japan”, Journal of Finance, 53,
SOU 2000:11 |
Volym D:47 |
|
|
Politics, Law and Financial Development
by
Raghuram G. Rajan *
and
Luigi Zingales **
Supplement number 24 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Views, suggestions, and opinions expressed in this study represent the personal views of the authors and not necessarily those of the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
October, 1999
*Joseph L. Gidwitz Professor of Finance, University of Chicago, Financial Management Area, Graduate School of Business. 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, USA.
**Professor of Finance, University of Chicago, Financial Management Area, Graduate School of Business. 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, USA.
Volym D:48 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Table of Contents
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish) ....................................................... |
50 |
|
Abstract ................................................................................................ |
51 |
|
Introduction.......................................................................................... |
52 |
|
1 |
Financial development across countries....................................... |
63 |
2 |
Fixed costs and |
|
|
backwardness............................................................................... |
68 |
3 |
The Nature of the Law................................................................. |
72 |
3.1 |
Legal Systems: Common Law and Civil Law ........................... |
73 |
4 |
Does the Legal System Really Matter for Financial |
|
|
Development?............................................................................... |
76 |
4.1 |
Law Enforcement..................................................................... |
76 |
4.2 |
Investor Protection................................................................... |
77 |
4.3 |
Measurement Ahead of Theory ................................................ |
79 |
4.4 |
Common Law as a Process ...................................................... |
81 |
4.5 |
Legal Incompleteness – Some examples.................................... |
82 |
4.6 |
Corporate Opportunity............................................................. |
83 |
4.7 |
Adaptation in Civil Law........................................................... |
84 |
5 |
The Superiority of Common Law: A Historical Test .................. |
86 |
6 |
A Political Economy of Financial Development ........................... |
94 |
6.1Why the Dominant Elite May Oppose Financial Development?. 94
6.2 |
Financial Markets and the Government..................................... |
96 |
6.3 |
Interaction Between Politics and the Law ................................. |
98 |
7 |
Back to History............................................................................ |
99 |
7.1 |
Early Financial Centers............................................................ |
99 |
7.2 |
The Emergence of London ..................................................... |
100 |
7.3 |
The French Experience .......................................................... |
103 |
7.4 |
British and Spanish colonies................................................... |
107 |
7.5 |
The Contrast with the Netherlands ......................................... |
108 |
7.6 |
The Triumph of the Bourgeoisie............................................. |
110 |
8 |
The Reaction .............................................................................. |
112 |
9 |
Policy Implications..................................................................... |
119 |
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:49 |
10 Conclusions |
................................................................................ 123 |
References........................................................................................... |
124 |
Volym D:50 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish)
Forskning under senare år visar att utvecklingen av ett lands finansiella marknader och institutioner tydligt påverkar den ekonomiska tillväxten i en positiv riktning. Frågan är då varför inte de finansiella marknader och institutioner som ett land behöver uppstår automatiskt. Historien visar att de institutionella hindren för ekonomisk utveckling nästan undantagslöst är politiska. Centraliserad och oinskränkt politisk makt har alltid hämmat ekonomisk utveckling. Detta är en förklaring till varför den finansiella utvecklingen inte har skett i jämn takt utan med språng, där politiska händelser som krig och revolutioner har hämmat eller t.o.m. reverserat utvecklingen. Ekonomiska marknader nådde i många länder en höjdpunkt strax före första världskriget, kollapsade med kriget och dess följder, och har återhämtat sig först under det senaste årtiondet. Det juridiska systemets utformning i dessa länder har varit en orsak till utvecklingen, dock endast en bidragande orsak.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:51 |
|
|
Abstract
In recent years, research has shown that the development of a country’s financial markets and institutions contribute substantially to its subsequent economic growth. But why does finance not develop to meet a country’s needs? History suggests that the institutional impediment to financial development is almost always political. In particular, centralized and unconstrained political power has invariably retarded financial development. This can explain why financial development has not progressed smoothly but has had ups and downs, buffeted by political events such as war and revolution. Financial markets in many countries reached their pinnacle just before the First World War, collapsed with the war and its aftermath, and have reemerged only in the last decade. The nature of the legal system in these countries plays only a supporting role in explaining what happened.
Volym D:52 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Introduction1
The development of a country’s financial markets and institutions dramatically increases the growth of industries, such as Computers or Pharmaceuticals, that need a lot of external,
But how can an economy reach this utopia? In other words, what drives the development of financial markets and institutions? The simple answer, and one favored by many economists, is demand. When opportunities arise in an economy that require financing, the economy will develop the necessary markets and institutions to finance these opportunities. For example, the enormous financing requirements of railroads in the United States (one billion dollars up to 1867 and 10 billion up to 1890) lead to the development of public markets for corporate debt and later for stock, with 40 % of this capital coming from Europe.4 Financial institutions such as investment banks, including the famous Morgan bank, emerged to underwrite and distribute these securities and to reassure European investors that the money was properly invested. Thus the needs of the railroads lead to the creation of financial infrastructure in the United States that was then available to finance other industries that came later. What we have just described is nothing but the reverse of Say’s Law – demand creates its own supply.
Unfortunately, this is, almost always, an oversimplification. It cannot explain why countries at a similar level of economic development differ
1Prepared for the Symposium on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Industry organized by the Bank of Sweden Tercentenary Foundation. We benefitted from conversations with Randy Kroszner, Kristian Rydqvist, Andrei Schleifer, and Rob Vishny.
2See Rajan and Zingales (1998a).
3See Rajan and Zingales (2000).
4See Engelbourg and Bushkoff (1996) and Chandler (1990).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:53 |
|
|
so much in the level of their financial development. While there is great controversy on how to measure financial development properly, there is little disagreement that, overall,
The failure of our version of Say’s law could be attributed to four,
We will argue that this factor should not be ignored in underdeveloped economies or geographically isolated communities, but it is not a satisfactory explanation for the differences in financial development across countries. It is hard to argue that financial systems in Continental Europe today are underdeveloped relative to Anglo- American ones because the amount of funds that need to be intermediated in Continental Europe is not sufficient to pay for the initial
A second impediment in the way of finance responding to economic needs is the time required to acquire knowledge and develop certain skills. For example, most banks today extend credit to their clientele on the basis of formal models of the credit worthiness of the borrowers. These models are based on statistical estimates of the influence various indicators have in predicting default. Thus, they can only be adopted when there exists a large enough data set with the borrower characteristics and default histories, so that financial intermediaries can compute reliable estimates. Obviously, these data and the accompanying evaluation expertise cannot be created overnight, but require time to
5 See La Porta et al. (1997).
Volym D:54 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
build. Another factor that requires time to build is reputation. Due to the difficulties in writing and enforcing fully comprehensive contracts, the reputation of the parties involved becomes essential in smoothing the working of financial markets. Reputations cannot be acquired overnight: they can only be built slowly.
The
Even after the
The third potential explanation for why the demand for financing does not automatically generate its own supply is the need for an enabling infrastructure. In a financial contract, the parties exchange money for the promise of more money in the future. The value of this promise, however, depends crucially on the legal environment. The legal environment affects the possibility of writing certain contracts, the precision and speed with which these contracts are enforced by courts, and the punishment imposed in case these contracts are breached. For example, in the 18th century it was impossible for private parties to create a limited liability corporation without the consent of the Crown. Even today certain legal systems do not recognize or enforce certain contracts. For example, the possibility of obtaining a loan secured by the value of the entire company is a standard contract in England (called floating charge), but it is not enforced in the United States. Similarly,
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:55 |
|
|
most Continental European codes ban legal fees contingent on outcome, which are common practice in the United States.
These differences in legal system might matter. Recent influential research by La Porta et al (1997, 1998) finds countries belonging to the Common Law tradition have more statutes protecting investors, and more developed financial markets. But if certain norms or statutes are better in promoting financial development, why do other countries not simply adopt them? For instance, while joint stock companies were first allowed to incorporate freely in England in 1853, the concept was quickly imitated in France, where laws passed in 1863 and 1867 allowed free incorporation. Thus, while different legal systems might have a different propensity to generate legal and contractual innovation, in principle there is no restriction to imitation, eliminating the possibility of enduring differences in the level of financial development. In fact, we will show that with the exception of England, the most developed countries in the world had a similar level of financial market development in 1913. The differences in the legal system existed then also, suggesting that if they did not create differences in financial development then, we should not attribute differences in financial development between countries today solely to differences in legal system.
This leads us to the last possible cause of financial backwardness: the lack of political support in favor of financial development. Governments have great influence on financial markets. Excessive regulation and taxation (or worse expropriation) can kill a market, as can the lack of just and swift enforcement of contracts. The government also has an important role in designing and enforcing laws. Thus, it is obvious that the lack of political support can seriously jeopardize financial development. But why do some political systems foster financial development, while others do not?
Before answering this question, we need to review the working of the political system and its two main players: the main interest groups and the Government. Interest groups pressure the government to favor them. The nature of the government – whether democratic, oligarchic or a monarchy – will determine which group has more saying and to what extent its wishes get translated into actions. But the government does not simply reflect the wishes of the dominant interest group, it also has its own agenda. This is clearly the case in a monarchy, but also in a democracy where the entrenched government bureaucracy has its own perks and survival at stake. Thus, asking why some political systems oppose financial development is tantamount to asking why some influential groups or the Government (or both) oppose financial development.
Volym D:56 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
There are certainly groups that win and those that lose from financial development. In a primitive financial system, the only people who can take advantage of profitable new opportunities are those that have the financial resources to do so, or can easily gather them using as collateral their stock of initial wealth. These sources of Old Wealth have an incentive to prevent competition by opposing financial development. Moreover, even if the Old Wealth is incapable of taking advantage of the opportunities, it has an incentive to prevent others from doing so since its relative position and power is much better in an underdeveloped economy, and the resources it can command greater. Thus, for example, the
By contrast, the industrial bourgeoisie has strong incentives to press for financial development, because of the tremendous opportunities it affords them to improve their lot. This may explain why the countries of Continental Europe developed vibrant financial markets only after the bourgeois revolutions of 1848 and beyond. Russia, on the other hand, never had such a revolution and, probably as a result, had the most underdeveloped markets in Europe. As Gerschenkron (1962) argues, the Russian elites actively opposed financial development and it was the state that had to finance large investment such as the railways. Thus, the exent to which the dominant elite support or oppose financial development crucially depends on the nature of the dominant elite and of the opportunities it faces.
Also the Government itself can be in favor or against financial development, depending on the circumstances. The opposition arises for two reasons. First, the emergence of vibrant financial markets and institutions requires constitutional limitations on the arbitrary powers of government, in particular to ensure that investors’ property rights are protected against expropriation. These limitations may impede government ambitions in other areas. Moreover, even when governments do become
6 See Ueda (1994).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:57 |
|
|
market. Of course, government can also be a force for the development of financial system if it is also in its own interest.
Finally, the ability of the dominant elite and the Government to affect the final outcome is not independent of the legal and political system. A political system where power is more concentrated makes it easier for a Government to act swiftly. Similarly, a legal system where the legislator makes the law, as in the civil law system, facilitates Government intervention, while a legal system based on precedents, like the common law one, makes it more difficult for the Government to alter the status quo. Thus, the political will of the Government and/or the dominant elite does not translate into action in the same way in different legal environments. Actions, whether favorable to or against financial development, will bear fruit more quickly in more centralized Governments and in civil law countries.
Can this theory explain the historical evolution of financial markets? It certainly is consistent with the broad outlines. Consistent with the political theory, all the early financial centers of the Modern world, starting with Florence and Venice, moving on to Hamburg and the cities of the Hanseatic League, and culminating in Amsterdam, emerged in little independent political entities controlled by the bourgeoisie. None of the political centers of big and powerful centralized states (Paris, Madrid, or Vienna) emerged early on as important financial centers. Also the emergence of London can be traced to the fortuitous coincidence of the two crucial catalysts predicted by the theory: an elite who could benefit from financial development and a weak Government. In England, as in all the other States, the dominant elite was the land aristocracy (gentry). But unlike other States the English land aristocracy in the 17th century could benefit from a development of the capital markets. About the same time, the English crown, which had lost its credibility by expropriating bankers in the famous Stop on the Exchequer (1672), was forced to introduce reforms that facilitated its own borrowing, and coincidentally, financial development. The result was that by the end of the 18th century London emerged as the financial capital of the world.
This predominance of London carried well into the 20th century. But during the second half of the 19th century, other financial centers started to emerge: not only New York, but also Paris and, to a less extent, Berlin. In fact, in 1907 the total amount of securities traded in Paris was slightly larger than that traded in New York, despite the fact that French GNP was only one fourth of U.S. GNP.7 Interestingly, 58 % of the securities traded in Paris were foreign, while almost no foreign securities
7 Davis and Neal (1998).
Volym D:58 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
traded in the U.S. Thus, in spite of a slow start, Paris had become the second financial capital of the world. What explains this catch up?
The second half of the nineteenth century saw, according to Eric Hobbsbawm, the Age of Capitalism and the triumph of pro market forces. The revolutions following 1848 put the bourgeoisie in power in most European states. The prolonged period of peace in Europe, between 1870 and 1914, brought economic interests to the fore. The major countries of Europe went on the Gold Standard to facilitate
”The world is becoming one in an altogether new sense…As the earth has been narrowed through the new forces science has placed at our disposal…the movements of politics, of economics, and of thought, in each of its regions, become more closely interwoven…Whatever happens in any part of the globe has now a significance for every other part. World History is tending to become One History.” 8
With the industrial bourgeoisie in power, Governments throughout Europe promoted financial development. Where legislative power was more concentrated at the top, as in civil law countries, this promarket intervention could be more effective. While it took over a century and a half for the English common law system to work out the limited liability form to its satisfaction, ten years were sufficient for the French civil code to imitate it. This explains the almost instant success of Continental European Governments in promoting financial development.
But World War I and its aftermath changed everything. Financial markets declined significantly in many countries between 1913 and 1948 even as a proportion of GDP, and in some cases have not reverted back to their prewar level even today. In Italy, for example, the number of publicly traded companies was higher in 1913 than in 1985.9 Interestingly, this decline was experienced not only by countries that lost one or both wars, but also by countries (like France) that won both, and even by countries, like Sweden, that did not participate in either. What caused the retreat of financial markets? Why was it more pronounced in some countries than in others?
8Address on April 3, 1913 of Mr Bryce, President of the International Congress of Historical Studies, cited in Powell (1915), p. 704.
9Pagano, Panetta, and Zingales (1998).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:59 |
|
|
In our view, there were two main reasons; one a bottomup upwelling of the desire for insurance, the other, a top down desire for national security that required the coordination of national resources. These political forces managed to assert themselves, especially in economies with centralizing tendencies. Since insurance and coordination of the kind desired are not easily supplied by the market, the market was forced to retreat in country after country, and supplanted by hierarchical organizational structures.
Let us explain in greater detail. The expansion of markets creates risks, which are not easily insured. For example, the lowering of trade barriers by an economy motivated by international trade could lead to entire industries becoming uncompetitive and the human capital of their workers redundant. It is hard to insure against this risk because the risk is hard to diversify away, and also insurance breeds standard problems of moral hazard and adverse selection.
Similarly, the existence of competitive arm’s length securities markets makes it harder for long term
More generally, as first suggested by Polanyi (1944), competitive markets whether in labor, industry, or finance tend to put strains on social relationships, which are based on implicit contracts. These social relationships are the primary source of insurance before the advent of the market. Moreover, markets tend to accentuate the difference between the incompetent, the unskilled, or the untalented and the more qualified, thus exacerbating the need for insurance. Thus competitive markets destroy old sources of insurance while creating new needs for it. Unfortunately, competition again – when coupled with the lack of commitment that
10 This idea was initially proposed by C.Mayer ”New Issues in Corporate Finance”, European Economic Review, 32 (1988), p.
Volym D:60 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
leads to incomplete contracting or
In good times, the greater allocative efficiency of the market papers over the lack of insurance. Everyone benefits from the rise in incomes. But in major downturns, the political pressure from the large masses of losers becomes hard to resist. In particular, the
In order to provide insurance in the form of higher employment, higher prices or wages to certain sectors, and financial sector stability, governments had to intervene massively in the working of markets – be they financial, labor or trade. But these typically distortionary actions were hard to undertake while the economy remained open to international competition. Protectionist tendencies therefore came to the fore. As more and more countries closed themselves off from the international economy, and went off the Gold Standard so as to better effect internal
The
The intensity of this
11 For models showing the difficulties of
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:61 |
|
|
where the legislature makes the law, became an easy prey for the political movements advocating a command and control system. Common Law provided a stronger bulwark against centralization. First, the English common law tradition emphasizes restraining the government and protecting the individual, making more difficult the centralization of the economy. Second, Common Law is based primarily on judicial precedent, rather than upon the act of a legislator. Thus, a new political climate is less able to transform the structure of society. Third, even though Common Law is hard to change from the center, it evolves at the periphery, and innovates around legislative or administrative roadblocks set up by the center. In our view the decentralized nature of the Common Law system, and its ability to resist
Our analysis emphasizes the importance that political consensus (or lack of) plays in the development and defense of markets in general and financial markets in particular. Its implications are not that all countries that did not have the good ”fortune” of being colonized by the British should adopt British common law. Rather, it is a note of caution against taking for granted that financial development is unidirectional, and that the generalized consensus in favor of markets is irreversible because of their obvious efficiency. History shows that in time of crisis a political backlash may occur and it can have very
To summarize our main thesis:
1)Financial development results when the politically powerful develop a consensus in its favor.
2)The centralization of political power in an economy tends to magnify the interests of those in power. This can speed up financial development when the center is in favor of markets – an all too rare occurrence – and reverse it when it is not.
3)Decentralization of political power, coupled with an efficient legal system tends to be most conducive for the protection of property rights and the financial innovation necessary for financial development. Decentralization also ensures that financial development is hard to reverse when the consensus at the center changes.
4)A Common Law system allows for more contractual and legal innovation, which makes it easier to by pass the potential roadblock imposed by an elite that opposes financial development. Hence it is
Volym D:62 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
more conducive to financial development. But its innovations can easily be imitated by a suitably motivated Civil law system. Thus, the greater financial development in Common Law countries is not because laws are better in those countries, but because the decentralization of Common Law makes it easier for financial markets to develop in spite of political opposition and makes it harder to reverse this development in the face of political challenges.
Now that we have laid down the main arguments, we move to explore them in greater detail. In the first section we present some aggregate data on the differences in financial development across countries. Section 2 briefly reviews the fixed costs and
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:63 |
|
|
1Financial development across countries
There is no consensus on the correct method to measure financial development. Theoretically, the right measure would be the ease with which companies in need of external funds can access them and the premium they have to pay for these funds. Unfortunately, these are not measures that can be easily computed even in the most developed countries, let alone for a large cross section of countries.
Thus, the standard practice, which we will follow here, is to compute ratios of the size of different components of the financial system to measures of the size of the economy. Table 1 reports such indicators for all the countries that have a stock exchange listed with the Federation International Bourse Valeurs (FIBV), the international association of Stock Exchanges.12 Even though this is a fairly comprehensive list, which includes a lot of developing and former socialist economies, it is important to note that countries enter the sample only if they have a stock exchange.
For ease of comparison, the countries are ordered in terms of per capita GDP at the end of 1996. The first measure reported is stock market capitalization over GDP. While there is a positive correlation between relative size of the stock market and the level of economic development (measured as per capita income), this association is far from overwhelming. Germany and the Netherlands are two countries that are very similar in every dimension (including the level of per capita GDP), but in the Netherlands the equity market capitalization is almost as much as the GDP, while in Germany only 30 %. The same can be said for the Philippines and Indonesia. Thus, the size of the equity market does not seem to be a simple reflection of the level of economic development.
12 We omit information for Azerbaijan, Croatia, Ivory Coast, Jugoslavia, Lebanon, Luxembourg, Hong Kong, and Taiwan because the International Financial Statistics do not report GNP data for these countries.
Volym D:64 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Table 1. Financial and Economic Development around the World 1996, end of
year data
|
|
Equity |
Bond |
Domestic |
|
Equity |
Bond |
|
Country |
Per capita |
market |
Market |
Credit |
Total |
raised |
raised |
Total |
|
GDP |
over GDP |
GDP |
over GDP |
over GDP |
over GCF |
over GCF |
over GCF |
Switzerland |
38,147 |
1.48 |
0.37 |
1.67 |
3.52 |
NA |
0.25 |
NA |
Norway |
36,047 |
0.36 |
0.14 |
0.59 |
1.09 |
0.04 |
0.08 |
0.12 |
Japan |
34,434 |
0.72 |
0.04 |
1.15 |
1.91 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
Denmark |
34,062 |
0.40 |
0.99 |
0.31 |
1.70 |
0.03 |
0.63 |
0.66 |
USA |
28,766 |
1.11 |
0.03 |
0.45 |
1.59 |
0.17 |
0.60 |
0.76 |
Sweden |
27,833 |
0.98 |
0.45 |
0.37 |
1.80 |
0.09 |
0.32 |
0.42 |
Austria |
26,702 |
0.16 |
0.19 |
1.01 |
1.36 |
0.01 |
0.09 |
0.10 |
France |
25,712 |
0.39 |
0.11 |
0.82 |
1.32 |
0.05 |
0.10 |
0.15 |
Belgium |
25,664 |
0.46 |
0.01 |
0.66 |
1.14 |
0.06 |
0.02 |
0.09 |
Singapore |
25,317 |
1.62 |
NA |
0.96 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
Netherlands |
24,464 |
0.99 |
0.35 |
1.06 |
2.40 |
0.18 |
0.29 |
0.47 |
Germany |
23,151 |
0.35 |
0.59 |
1.26 |
2.20 |
0.04 |
NA |
NA |
Australia |
21,705 |
0.78 |
0.00 |
0.78 |
1.56 |
0.15 |
NA |
NA |
Finland |
21,651 |
0.56 |
0.08 |
0.68 |
1.32 |
0.03 |
0.09 |
0.13 |
UK |
21,348 |
1.31 |
0.22 |
1.23 |
2.76 |
0.17 |
0.33 |
0.50 |
Italy |
21,335 |
0.21 |
0.03 |
0.51 |
0.75 |
0.02 |
0.05 |
0.07 |
Ireland |
20,051 |
0.49 |
NA |
0.36 |
NA |
NA |
0.11 |
NA |
Canada |
19,978 |
0.81 |
0.00 |
0.47 |
1.28 |
0.09 |
0.00 |
0.09 |
New Zealand |
18,963 |
0.54 |
NA |
0.92 |
NA |
0.10 |
0.02 |
0.11 |
Kuwait |
17,670 |
0.61 |
NA |
0.34 |
NA |
1.18 |
NA |
NA |
Israel |
16,347 |
0.37 |
0.03 |
0.72 |
1.13 |
0.03 |
0.00 |
0.03 |
Spain |
14,398 |
0.43 |
0.02 |
0.71 |
1.16 |
NA |
0.05 |
NA |
Greece |
11,505 |
0.20 |
0.01 |
0.23 |
0.44 |
0.03 |
0.03 |
0.05 |
Portugal |
10,758 |
0.23 |
0.06 |
0.67 |
0.96 |
0.03 |
NA |
NA |
Korea |
10,146 |
0.30 |
0.19 |
0.64 |
1.13 |
0.04 |
0.22 |
0.26 |
Slovenia |
9,142 |
0.05 |
0.00 |
0.29 |
0.34 |
0.09 |
0.01 |
0.10 |
Bahrain |
8,908 |
0.94 |
NA |
0.97 |
NA |
0.04 |
NA |
NA |
Argentina |
8,448 |
0.15 |
0.01 |
0.18 |
0.34 |
NA |
0.06 |
NA |
Oman |
7,182 |
0.20 |
NA |
0.26 |
NA |
0.10 |
NA |
NA |
Uruguay |
5,476 |
0.02 |
NA |
0.29 |
NA |
0.00 |
NA |
NA |
Czech Republic |
5,012 |
0.28 |
NA |
0.62 |
NA |
0.15 |
NA |
NA |
Brazil |
4,742 |
0.29 |
0.00 |
0.26 |
0.55 |
0.08 |
NA |
NA |
Chile |
4,672 |
0.98 |
0.18 |
0.56 |
1.72 |
0.14 |
0.15 |
0.29 |
Malaysia |
4,666 |
3.10 |
0.03 |
0.93 |
4.07 |
0.14 |
0.04 |
0.18 |
Hungary |
4,158 |
0.12 |
NA |
0.18 |
NA |
0.05 |
NA |
NA |
Slovakia |
3,362 |
0.07 |
NA |
0.32 |
NA |
0.00 |
NA |
NA |
Mexico |
3,353 |
0.33 |
0.02 |
0.18 |
0.53 |
0.01 |
0.02 |
0.04 |
Poland |
3,278 |
0.07 |
0.00 |
0.16 |
0.23 |
0.01 |
0.00 |
0.01 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:65 |
||||||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Equity |
Bond |
Domestic |
|
Equity |
Bond |
|
|
|
Country |
Per capita |
market |
Market |
Credit |
Total |
raised |
raised |
Total |
|
|
|
GDP |
over GDP |
GDP |
over GDP |
over GDP |
over GCF |
over GCF |
over GCF |
|
|
Panama |
3,034 |
0.16 |
NA |
0.78 |
NA |
0.00 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Thailand |
2,990 |
0.53 |
0.00 |
1.02 |
1.55 |
0.06 |
0.00 |
0.06 |
|
|
Russia |
2,742 |
0.00 |
NA |
0.07 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
South Africa |
2,736 |
2.06 |
0.01 |
0.70 |
2.77 |
0.30 |
0.00 |
0.30 |
|
|
Venezuela |
2,714 |
0.16 |
NA |
0.08 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Botswana |
2,686 |
0.08 |
NA |
0.11 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Jamaica |
2,557 |
0.30 |
NA |
0.24 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Costa Rica |
2,505 |
0.09 |
NA |
0.18 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Colombia |
2,503 |
0.15 |
NA |
0.21 |
NA |
0.05 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Peru |
2,407 |
0.22 |
0.02 |
0.19 |
0.43 |
0.02 |
0.04 |
0.06 |
|
|
Iran |
2,179 |
0.10 |
NA |
0.18 |
NA |
0.03 |
0.00 |
0.03 |
|
|
Lithuania |
2,127 |
0.16 |
NA |
0.11 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Turkey |
2,118 |
0.23 |
0.00 |
0.22 |
0.45 |
0.04 |
0.02 |
0.06 |
|
|
Paraguay |
1,889 |
0.04 |
NA |
0.23 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Tunisia |
1,542 |
0.27 |
NA |
0.67 |
NA |
0.07 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Equador |
1,435 |
0.13 |
NA |
0.27 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Marocco |
1,321 |
0.24 |
NA |
0.28 |
NA |
0.09 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Jordan |
1,299 |
0.67 |
NA |
0.65 |
NA |
0.11 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Swaziland |
1,209 |
0.41 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Latvia |
1,209 |
0.05 |
NA |
0.12 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Philippines |
1,162 |
0.96 |
0.00 |
0.48 |
1.45 |
0.08 |
0.00 |
0.08 |
|
|
Indonesia |
1,137 |
0.40 |
0.00 |
0.55 |
0.96 |
0.08 |
0.00 |
0.08 |
|
|
Namibia |
1,113 |
0.27 |
NA |
0.69 |
NA |
3.58 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Egypt |
1,108 |
0.21 |
NA |
0.37 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Sri Lanka |
738 |
0.14 |
NA |
0.25 |
NA |
0.04 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Zimbabwe |
664 |
0.46 |
NA |
0.21 |
NA |
0.06 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
China |
663 |
0.08 |
NA |
0.94 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Honduras |
610 |
NA |
NA |
0.23 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Bulgaria |
428 |
0.00 |
NA |
0.36 |
NA |
0.00 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Pakistan |
404 |
0.22 |
NA |
0.25 |
NA |
0.07 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Nigeria |
383 |
0.31 |
NA |
0.12 |
NA |
0.08 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
India |
380 |
0.34 |
NA |
0.26 |
NA |
0.11 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Zambia |
373 |
0.07 |
NA |
0.09 |
NA |
NA |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Ghana |
346 |
0.27 |
NA |
0.06 |
NA |
0.07 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Kenya |
296 |
0.19 |
NA |
0.28 |
NA |
0.05 |
NA |
NA |
|
|
Bangladesh |
255 |
0.11 |
NA |
0.28 |
NA |
0.02 |
NA |
NA |
|
Sources: FIBV, Annual Reports and IMF: International Financial Statistics.
Volym D:66 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
This is true also for the size of the bond market. While the available data from the FIBV suggests a stronger association between the level of economic development and the size of the bond market, this is not the entire story. For example, Italy and the United Kingdom have a similar per capita income, but very different bond markets (3 % of GDP for Italy, 22 % for the U.K.). Interestingly, among the countries for which data are available there is no association between the level of development of the bond market and that of the equity market. Germany, which has a relatively small equity market (35 % of GDP) has a relatively large bond market (59 %).
A third indicator of financial development, although not necessarily an indicator of development of financial markets, is the amount of domestic credit over GDP. This is a measure of the amount of credit extended by banks. Again there is a strong association between this indicator and the per capita income, as also considerable unexplained variation: Austria, which has a per capita income very similar to Sweden, has three times the level of credit per unit of GDP. Similarly, the U.K. has two and a half times the level of domestic credit as Italy. Interestingly, the level of domestic credit is positively correlated with the importance of the equity market, suggesting complementarity rather than substitution between the two. Some countries appear to be more financially developed on every dimension.
One important drawback of the above measures is that they record the stock of financial instruments outstanding, rather than the flow of investments intermediated by the financial system. This drawback is particularly serious in the case of the equity market capitalization, which measures the market value of the existing companies rather than the amount of funds raised in the equity market. Thus, the Dutch stock market appears very large because of the presence of the oil giant Royal Dutch Shell. But Royal Dutch Shell does not raise much funds externally, thus its presence in the Netherlands does not necessarily indicate that companies can raise funds easily in the Dutch equity market. A better measure, therefore, is the fraction of total investment that is financed by equity issues (the sum of equity issued in secondary markets by publicly traded companies and shares sold at the initial public offering by newly listed firms). Unfortunately, this datum is not available for many countries. For the countries for which it is available, however, it confirms the previous results. The level of financial development differs greatly across countries even if we compare countries with a similar level of economic development. Furthermore,
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:67 |
|
|
the rest of the world (16 % vs. 6 % even after eliminating Namibia, which is a big outlier).
The data on funds raised through bond issues should be interpreted with caution because they are gross bond issues, that is, they do not subtract the amount of bond retirement. Nevertheless, they seem to confirm the overall pattern, as do the sum of the two.
In sum, the data on financial development around the world seem to reject a simple variant of Say’s law. Financial development does not go
Volym D:68 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
2Fixed costs and
Clearly, there are large fixed costs in setting up financial infrastructure.13 Furthermore, it may be hard for private enterprise to internalize all the gains to doing so, especially if these gains are spread over a long period of time. If there is no preexisting financial infrastructure, the economy needs either the fortuitous combination of rich individuals with the will at a time when there is a sudden large demand for financing (or a farsighted government that can pool resources) for the infrastructure to be set up. Chandler (1977) suggests this is, in fact, what happened in the United States. The financial sector, especially investment banks and the corporate bond market, developed to meet the enormous financing needs of railroads in the midnineteenth century. The total investment in American railroads came to a billion dollars in 1867, three billion in 1873, five billion in 1880, and fully ten billion in 1890.14 This was far in excess of the financing ability of a young nation, especially given the enormous financial strains caused by the civil war. Therefore, the source for over forty percent of this capital before 1914 was Europe.
At that time, capital in Europe could be obtained for about half its cost in the United States. But European investors were fearful due to the lack of reliable information and the fact that ”legal and quasi legal safeguards for the buyer were almost entirely lacking. Recourse to American courts would hardly help investors in
Even after the
13For models on fixed costs of financial development and growth, see Bencivenga and Smith (1991) and Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990).
14Egelbourg and Bushkoff (1996).
15Egelbourg and Bushkoff (1996).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:69 |
|
|
perhaps most important is that a large number of persons think of that particular market as the natural location for their trades. Thus there is a chicken and egg problem with liquidity – people will not trade in a particular market unless they think the market is liquid, but the market will not be liquid unless they trade. This again implies that the birth of a market requires the rare event that serves to coordinate expectations. For example, the United States Government issued Liberty Bonds in large numbers to finance the war effort during the First World War. People who would otherwise not touch a financial security bought these bonds for patriotic reasons. Peach (1941) argues that it was the successful experience these investors had with the bonds that made them willing to invest in arm’s length securities issued by corporations, which then gave corporate securities markets liquidity, and led to the enormous expansion of these markets in the 1920s.
More generally, economic theory suggests that a market becomes liquid when, somewhat
Investors obtain such confidence, not from a detailed scrutiny of the financial press but from
Financial contracts also take time to perfect. There is a process of trial and error in which institutions initially, and eventually markets,
16 See Rajan and Servaes (1997).
Volym D:70 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
learn the nuances of a financial contract, how to price it, what covenants to build in, how to withstand legal scrutiny, and how to obtain effective enforcement.17 The institutions such as exchanges, audit agencies, custodial services, rating agencies, etc., that help the smooth enforcement of arm’s length contracts take time to set up, and more time to perfect their trade in local conditions.
Financial intermediaries also take time to set up and become effective. As Rajan (1998) argues, institutions intermediate where financial contracts are incomplete, either because contingencies cannot be fully foreseen in the case of innovative transactions, or because the contingencies are too complex to describe up front. The institution uses its reputation to bond itself, and its bargaining power to achieve negotiated outcomes that are superior to those that can be obtained through direct transacting in the market place. A good reputation is crucial for an intermediary because this is what convinces customers to trust it when contracts do not fully protect them, but reputations take time to build, see Kreps and Wilson (1982) and Diamond (1989), for example.18 An institution may also be able to bond itself by putting its monetary capital or future rents at stake, but we have already argued that monetary capital may not be available in concentrated form in economies with primitive financial sectors. Moreover, even if available, monetary capital alone may not be particularly effective in providing assurances to customers, see Boot, Greenbaum, and Thakor (1993).
Finally, financial intermediaries take time to build for the same reasons that large industrial firms take time to build, see Rajan and Zingales (1999). It takes time for employees to learn to work with each
17See Rajan (1998).
18In every financial innovation, there are outcomes that are not anticipated up front, and have to be worked out amicably between intermediary and client. This is where the intermediary's reputation plays a part. Some intermediaries develop reputations for being
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:71 |
|
|
other, to build relationships with customers, and to build routines that ensure the smooth functioning of the organization. Moreover, all this learning cannot take place instantaneously, it has to be sequenced, else it could risk overwhelming the command and control capabilities of the organization.
While these factors are clearly important in explaining what triggered the birth and early steps of a financial market, it is hardly a satisfactory explanation for today’s differences in financial development across countries that we reviewed in the previous section. It is hard to argue that the French financial system today is underdeveloped relative to the English one because the amount of funds that need to be intermediated in the French economy is not sufficient to pay for the initial
Volym D:72 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
3 The Nature of the Law
The third potential explanation for why the demand for financing does not automatically generate its own supply is the need for an enabling infrastructure. Since contracts lie at the heart of almost any financial arrangement, there is a growing consensus amongst economists that the law – which dictates permissible contracts, their interpretation, and the ease with which they can be enforced – must matter for financial development.
Clearly, specific laws make a difference to financial systems. For example, the great variety of financial institutions in the United States – ranging from traditional commercial banks to modern venture capitalists or boutiques specializing in trading derivative securities – is probably an outcome of the Glass Steagall Act of 1933, and other legislation introduced during the Great Depression. These laws, reflecting the age- old suspicion among the people of the Western frontier states of the United States of East Coast bankers, effectively curtailed the power of large financial institutions and prevented them from dominating any part of the financial sector.19 The different legal protection granted to minority shareholders has been shown to affect the value of corporate of control.20 Similarly, a study of
Perhaps a better starting point is not specific laws but the legal system – the way laws are formed and then enforced. Let us first describe how legal systems broadly differ across countries.
19See Roe (1994).
20Zingales (1995).
21See Rajan and Zingales (1995).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:73 |
|
|
3.1Legal Systems: Common Law and Civil Law
Most modern legal systems in market economies can be classified as either belonging to the Common law tradition or the Civil law tradition. The main difference between the two systems lies in who makes the law. In the Common law system, past judgements by higher courts have enormous weight. Statutes passed by legislators are, therefore, considerably refined, and even modified, by precedent set in cases by judges. By contrast, in the Civil law tradition, law is really made by legal theorists with the aim of achieving (at least theoretically) the end of justice. The proposed statutes are enacted by legislators, and become paramount. Judicial decisions do not create law, because that task, in the Civil law system, belongs solely to the legislative body. The judge tries to interpret logically the intent of the legislator in arriving at a just solution. But in practice, the courts are not completely at ease unless they can invoke one or more texts of enacted law to justify or support their judgement.22
While this is the main difference, there are related systematic differences in the two systems. Common Law evolved in England, and was never based on a code of laws even though the Romans had ruled England, and Roman law is the source code of most Civil codes. Over time, judges obtained enormous power because of their knowledge of precedent, and their ability to make law, and they resisted codification, which would force them to cede power to legislators and theorists. Of course, it also helped in England that while the Common law system was evolving, there were countervailing powers to the King such as rich nobles, who supported a judicial system that was not under the king’s thumb. As a result, the judicial system became a bulwark against the arbitrariness of the king. This is reflected in the kinds of cases that were initially tried under the common law system – matters relating to royal finances, ownership and possession of land, and serious criminal matters affecting the peace of the kingdom.23
The emphasis in the Common law system is in following ”due process”. Justice emerges from following the formalistic principles laid down such as the selection of the correct form of action or writ by which the court can be seized, convincing the court it has jurisdiction, and following the adversarial process of argument before a jury. The English attitude is that if a fair procedure is followed, a just solution
22David and Brierley (1979, p. 95).
23David and Brierley (1979, p. 291).
Volym D:74 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
automatically emerges. The emphasis on procedure is natural in a country where there was no prior body of law to refer to, and judges empirically created law.24
As a result, Common law is very open to any kind of question that can arise. Since it emphasizes method, answers to new questions can be found by starting with already enumerated rules and discovering the legal rule – perhaps a new one – which deserves to be applied in the specific case at hand. The facts of the case are very important, and if the judge arrives at a different decision from that suggested by precedent, it is because the facts are different.25 Thus Common law, according to legal theorists David and Brierley, is an ”open” system.
By contrast, the Civil law system originates from the code of Justinian, laid down at a time when there was a need to obtain some uniformity in the system of justice across a very diverse empire. It is quite suited to a centralized system because any legislation modifying the law cannot be altered by judges, who instead have to find just solutions within the confines of the statutes laid down by legislators. While this makes the law more responsive to central command, it adapts much more slowly to local conditions, especially to the idiosyncrasies of the particular case. Unlike the judge under Common law who looks for factual exceptions so as to break from precedent, the judge under Civil law looks for statutes the judgement can conform to. As a result, the Civil law system is much more of a closed system.
Within the broad
24David and Brierley (1979, p. 331).
25David and Brierley (1979, p. 335).
26David and Brierley (1979, p.
27David and Brierley (1979, p. 113).
28David and Brierley (1979, p. 96).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:75 |
|
|
In drawing out the salient features of each legal tradition, we may have caricatured them a bit. This is the price we pay for brevity. But the caricature seems to match well with differences in dominant philosophy
– Common law corresponds to the empirical tradition of Locke and Hume while Civil law relates to the rationalist tradition of Descartes. Furthermore, abstraction from detail also has permitted economists to classify different countries in the world according to which tradition they most resemble. Countries adopt a particular legal system either because they developed it themselves, imitated the salient features of another country’s code, or because they were conquered or colonized, and the victor passed its system on. It is useful to see how differences in legal system affect financial development, and perhaps more important, analyze why they might have an influence.
Volym D:76 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
4Does the Legal System Really Matter for Financial Development?
There are three direct channels through which a legal system can affect financial development. In what follows we will discuss the sources of these effects as well as discuss the evidence on their empirical relevance.
4.1Law Enforcement
A financial contract is little more than a promise to repay some money in the future. The value of this promise depends crucially on the speed and efficiency with which courts provide remedies for breach. It is not only important whether a certain sum is repaid, it is also important when this sum is repaid and how reliable the expectation of repayment is. While efficient enforcement benefits all financial contracts, it benefits most arm’s length contracts, which lack alternative ways of enforcement. By contrast, contracts written in the context of repeated relationships do not rely solely on the courts, and can be enforced by the threat of interrupting the relationship. Thus, inefficient enforcement should especially jeopardize the development of financial markets
There is little doubt that law enforcement is important for financial development. La Porta et al (1997) find that a country’s ”law and order tradition” (as compiled by International Country Risk Guide) contributes to explaining the relative size of its financial markets. But this is far from being the whole story. Germany, for instance, scores near the top in all the index of efficiency of the judicial system and contract enforcement. In spite of that (and of its high level of economic development), it has a fairly minuscule market. Smaller than the one of a country like Thailand, which scores near the bottom of the list in all these measures.
More importantly, contract enforcement is, by a large extent, a policy variable. Thus, an explanation of financial development based entirely on the efficiency of contract enforcement would beg the question of why some countries enforce the law better than others. An explanation in this
29 See Rajan and Zingales (1998) for a development of this argument.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:77 |
|
|
sense can only be found moving to a political view of financial development, avenue that we will pursue in Section 4.
4.2Investor Protection
The traditional legal approach to Corporate Law was positing that contract enforcement is all that is needed for financial development. Rational investors will write in financial contracts all the necessary clauses to protect themselves. The State only role, then, would be to enforce these contracts in a prompt and just manner.
When it comes to public markets, however, two problems emerge. First, dispersed buyers find it impossible to bargain on the specific legal details of a security. They are just left with the option to buy a financial instrument ”as is” or not to buy it. In this situation, a set of prespecified rights granted by the law can reduce contracting costs. Second, dispersed investors find it costly to enforce their rights. By standardizing the rights, explicit laws may facilitate enforcement. Thus, it is possible that better laws designed to protect investors might foster financial development. The direction of causality, however, is not clear. More advanced financial markets have more experience on what it is needed to protect investors. They are, thus, more likely to pass laws in this direction.
To try to disentangle the direction of causality, La Porta et al. investigate whether the degree of investor protection differs as a function of the family of origin of a country’s legal system. Countries adopted a particular legal system centuries ago, mostly as a result of an invasion or colonization. If, more than a century later, the type of system adopted has an effect on the level of investor protection and financial development, then – the authors claim – there is a ”strong case that legal families, as expressed in the legal rules, actually affect outcomes”. 30
In a series of influential papers, La Porta et al. show that indeed Common Law countries protect investors better. This is true not only for equity investors, but also for creditors. They then go on to relate cross- country differences in financial development with the family of origin of a country’s legal system. In discussing Table 1, we have already pointed out that the U.K and its former colonies, which are Common Law countries, have a much larger ratio of the size of stock market to GDP. The evidence presented by La Porta et al. (1997) is much more detailed. Common law countries have many more listed firms per million people and more initial public offerings per million people. For example, France
30 La Porta, et al. (1998, p. 1126).
Volym D:78 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
has 8 listed firms per million people in 1994 while Germany has only 5. By contrast, the United Kingdom has 36, the United States 30, and Israel an astonishing 128. This diversity in listed firms is also reflected in initial public offerings (IPO) of stock. In
These findings suggest that firms in common law countries tend to raise far more equity finance from public investors than do firms in civil law countries. They are especially striking because they hold across countries with dramatic differences in per capita GDP. For instance, India has more IPOs per million of population than any country following the French or German civil law tradition.
Moving to debt markets, countries from a German civil law tradition tend to have deeper debt markets than common law countries (on average, the private sector debt to GDP ratio is 0.97 in 1994). However, common law countries have larger debt markets (debt to GDP ratio of 0.68) than countries from a French (debt to GDP ratio of 0.45) or Scandinavian civil law tradition (debt to GDP ratio of 0.57).32 Some of the differences in debt ratios may be because what is regarded as debt differs across countries. For example, unlike in the United States, fully funded pension liabilities show up as debt in German balance sheets which gives the impression that German companies are highly indebted when, in reality, they are not. Moreover, more of the debt is borrowed from financial intermediaries in Germany compared to the United States where public corporate debt markets are quite large. Therefore, it may well be that countries from a common law tradition typically have both deeper public equity and debt markets.
A final piece of evidence; accounting standards have been used in other studies as a good proxy for financial development.33 Unlike measures of financial development based on market size, this measure of financial development is useful because it is not mechanically correlated with the amount of finance raised – which may be a function of the kinds of industries present in a country. Common Law countries again seem to be more financially developed than all but the Scandinavian countries because their rating on accounting standards is uniformly higher (on
31La Porta, et al. (1997, p.1137).
32La Porta, et al. (1997, p. 1138).
33See Rajan and Zingales (1998).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:79 |
|
|
average, 70) than French origin (average 51) and German origin (average 63) civil law countries.
In summary, these authors find separately that Common Law countries protect investors better and financial markets are better developed in these countries. The natural conclusion is that these are cause and effect. But the theme of their work, ”Law and Finance” hints at a broader idea, that it is the legal system more than any other difference between the countries that leads to the differences in financial development.
4.3Measurement Ahead of Theory
Even before looking at some new evidence, there are theoretical reasons to be cautious about drawing any conclusions, natural as they may seem. One has to make strong assumptions even to go from one finding to the other. For instance, while it may seem
Equally worrisome is the question of whether these studies capture the true degree of protection enjoyed by investors in different countries. This cannot be understood without being able to specify the nature of the investor and the threat to investor rights.
La Porta et al. focus mainly on the protection granted to minority shareholders and creditors against managers and dominant shareholders. But civil law countries may want to protect a different type of investor than minority shareholders or creditors. For example, investing may largely be done through institutions in some civil law countries. This is
34 See Rajan and Zingales (1995).
Volym D:80 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
also consistent with the finding in La Porta et al. that the three largest owners hold a greater fraction of shares in French civil law countries than in common law countries. These investors may not need the protection afforded minority investors that La Porta et al. focus on. There is clearly a problem of causality that cannot be disentangled. If civil law countries do indeed have poor minority investor protection, is it because corporations there do not need to attract such investors since finance is largely intermediated by financial institutions, or is the direction of causality as La Porta et al. suggest; French civil law countries have few minority investors because minority investor protection is so weak.
Most importantly, none of the rights investigated by La Porta et al. appears unique to a common law system – the rights are present in at least some of the civil law countries. If there is one thing that the civil- law tradition is good at, it is writing new laws in great detail. Why then do we have this apparent contradiction with civil law countries not introducing seemingly simple, but valuable, statutes that seem to exist in common law countries? Perhaps the failure to introduce laws to protect investors is symptomatic of other, deeper underlying factors.
One potential piece of evidence that investor protection may be a symptom and not an underlying cause for financial development is provided by La Porta et al. themselves. When their measures of equity market development (such as the number of listed firms per million population) are regressed against the country of origin of the legal system and the index of antidirector rights, the latter is either not significant or marginally statistically significant. When the debt to GNP ratio is similarly regressed, the index of creditor rights has no additional impact once the country of origin of the legal system is accounted for. One possibility is that the aspects of investor protection that are most important for financial development are best proxied for by legal origin. Alternatively, there is something else that is associated with legal origin that leads to financial development but is unrelated to investor protection. We will examine both possibilities in what follows.
To summarize, the seminal work by La Porta et al. strongly indicates that countries who have a legal system rooted in English common law tend to have better developed corporate capital markets. More controversial is their claim that the reason for this finding is the higher degree of investor protection granted by Common Law countries, especially because the theoretical link between the two is still missing.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:81 |
|
|
4.4Common Law as a Process
A third possibility is that Common Law is more helpful than Civil Law in making operational legal devices such as ownership, contracts, and corporate structures, and social constructs such as good faith. Therefore, it may not be the specific statutes but the process by which the legal decision is arrived at that puts Common Law countries at the vanguard of financial innovation and development.
The focus of a common law system is on adopting the right process to reach a just solution. The civil law system, instead, expects the judge to apply the law as it is written. These differences would be irrelevant in a world where all future contingencies are anticipated and written in the initial contract or in the law. But contracts are typically incomplete in that they do not specify the rights and duties of all parties in all possible situations that may arise.35 For example, when someone rents a house it is expected that he will subject it to reasonable wear and tear. What is meant by ”reasonable” is usually left unspecified, often because it is too costly to detail the myriad ways in which the house is abused. Instead, the owner and the renter negotiate after the rental period about whether the wear and tear is reasonable, and who will pay for it if not. If they do not agree, a court steps in.
Laws themselves are incomplete. While the judge may be equally capable of deciding what is just in a simple rental dispute in both the common law and civil law system, matters can be quite different as the legal form being fought over changes. We will argue that the focus of the common law system on adopting the right process to reach a just solution rather than creating the precise law up front allows it to deal with a far richer set of contingencies than the civil law system. This flexibility of the common law system allows more experimentation. Eventually, the case law stemming from such experimentation affords agents more certainty about the outcomes when a particular contract or form is used, and also results in a richer variety of contractual possibilities and legal forms. By facilitating contractual and legal adaptation, common law enables the ”production” of explicit and richly detailed arm's length contracts. This may partially be a factor why financial markets, entailing arm's length contracts between firms and investors, are more developed in common law countries. We now elaborate on this point.
35 See Grossman and Hart (1986).
Volym D:82 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
4.5Legal Incompleteness – Some examples
It may be useful to start with some examples of legal constructs that differ across the two systems and to understand what might drive the difference. We look at two important constructs – the concept of ownership and the notion of the corporation.
The legal system is important because it defines the content of the ownership or property right and its limitations. The content refers to the object that is owned, while the limitations are the restrictions imposed on the ability to contract over that particular object. Traditional Roman law defined the ownership of a piece of land as an unlimited right usque ad inferes et usque ad sidera (from the center of the earth to the stars). More operationally, the owner has three prerogatives over the property in civil law – the right to usus (use), fructus (enjoy the fruits of), and abusus (sell or destroy). An important difference between civil law and common law, according to legal theorists David and Brierley, is that civil law does not allow easy fragmentation of these rights, while common law does.36 This means that a variety of ownership structures are possible under common law, which are not under civil law.
For example, the concept of trust where the trustee has ownership rights and manages property in the interests of the trust beneficiary is alien to civil law. The trustee under Common Law has the right to administer and sell the property but does not use it and cannot destroy it. The beneficiary enjoys the fruits of the property, and perhaps the use, but does not have administrative control. Why cannot this structure which involves the fragmentation of ownership not appear easily in civil law countries?
The likely reason is that civil law cannot handle easily the myriad contingencies and exceptions that may arise in fragmenting ownership. What if the beneficiary and the trustee dispute a particular action such as the sale of property? Clearly, the resolution under common law would depend on the facts of the case, with the judgment trading off the need to be equitable to the beneficiary without hampering the administrative powers of the trustee. It is far harder under civil law to determine, a priori, where the balance of ownership rights should lie. Since legislature cannot make the determination, it is easier, though perhaps less efficient, to allow only simpler structures where ownership lies with the beneficiary and the trustee is simply the agent.
36 David and Brierley , p.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:83 |
|
|
4.6Corporate Opportunity
The ability to demarcate ownership precisely is not just important for relationships between owners and investors, it is also important in the creation and preservation of value. The value of a company is a combination of the value of its assets in place – such as plant and machinery – and the value of its investment opportunities – its plans for future growth. Assets in place are easily identifiable, and are protected by standard property law. By contrast, investment opportunities are harder to define and, as such, to protect. While it is fairly easy to prohibit an employee or director from competing with the corporation or from using corporate assets for personal use, it is not as easy to prevent her from taking advantage of a business opportunity.
Consider for instance the case of Guth vs. Loft. Guth, the president of Loft Inc a manufacturer and seller of beverages, bought the formula and trademark of the then bankrupt National
In the United States, the firm's right to opportunities is not protected by a specific law, but by a doctrine (the corporate opportunity doctrine). The concept is ambiguous. Courts disagree about the proper test for determining whether an opportunity is a ”corporate opportunity”, and case law attempts to define the doctrine more precisely. Nevertheless, the existence of this doctrine in the United States grants to an outside owner of the firm some control over investment opportunities, and allows her to capture at least some of their value. This makes possible, in the United States and in other common law countries, the financing of enterprises with valuable future opportunities but little assets.
The problems encountered in the United States in elaborating a universally accepted test of what constitutes a corporate opportunity illustrate the horrendous difficulties that would be faced in codifying this concept. Civil law would have to resolve much of the ambiguity up front. But ex ante complete codes are virtually impossible to write since many eventualities are impossible to foresee. Moreover, ambiguous
Volym D:84 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
concepts such as intent and good faith play a part in determining the appropriate outcomes. These concepts are again highly contextual, and are more amenable to being judged ex post, based on fact, rather than ex ante based on theory. Of course, we do not intend to imply that the judge in a civil law system has no discretion, and does not use the facts of the case to arrive at a judgement. All that we imply is the empirical emphasis of the common law system may make it superior in both defining the property that is owned and devising an appropriate sharing of the fruits from, and the control rights over, the property.
A country with a civil code has two options in attempting to delineate property rights among different claimants to the firm better. First, it can try to describe rights in a variety of contingencies that can be anticipated, perhaps leading to an inflexible code. This may imply that certain statutes that exist in common law countries – because they can be tempered in operation by the interpretation of the courts – will not exist in civil law countries because they will be overly rigid in operation.
Alternatively, civil law can describe some
4.7Adaptation in Civil Law
We have probably overstated the differences between a civil code and a common law system. It is only a matter of time before the most important contingencies associated with a certain contract are observed and appropriate law written. Why cannot civil law replicate what common law does, but with a lag? Instead of the courts making law through cases, the civil code could be modified after a number of judgements reveal the difficulties with the existing law. After all, because the authority to modify the law is centralized in the legislature, a civil law system permits easy modification.
Adaptation may not be perfect. If the law is not crafted in the necessary detail to begin with, the courts may not be confronted with the necessary cases that would suggest a change in the law. For instance, if there is no corporate opportunity doctrine to begin with, it is hard for courts to confront the issue and build up experience that would suggest how the law should be rewritten to define more precisely corporate opportunities that are the firms. On the other hand, having a blanket opportunity doctrine without allowing courts to interpret which ones are
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:85 |
|
|
legitimately the firm's may also not result in the necessary experience. Few employees would break away and start their own venture for fear that the product of their effort, if successful, would be deemed to belong to the firm. This could stifle innovation and entry and, equally important, prevent the challenges to the law that lead to its development. In other words, the ability of courts under common law to frame and interpret the law also encourages cases that test and challenge the law and lead to its development.
Civil Law countries could imitate Common Law countries. However, the wealth of collective experience from case law is hard to codify into precise statutes. It is, in a sense, tacit knowledge that is common knowledge among the participants in the system, but extremely hard to express verbally. Thus while in theory civil law could evolve to capture the richness of the collective experience reflected in common law, in practice adaptation may be delayed and imperfect.
Nevertheless, as we will show, complicated legal constructs such as the ability to freely incorporate with limited liability have been quickly adopted in their final form by Civil Law countries, even though they were perfected after a long period of experimentation in Common Law countries. Thus it seems implausible that the inability to deal with legal incompleteness is what holds Civil Law countries back in the long run.
Volym D:86 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
5The Superiority of Common Law: A Historical Test
La Porta et al. present overwhelmingly evidence that Common Law countries are more financially developed. Their proposed causal link, however, is fragile. If financial development requires statutes that protect investors and these statutes are not unique to Common Law, why others countries do not adopt them? Thus, it must be the case that the advantage of Common Law is not replicable, like the quality of its enforcement process rather than its efficiency. At this point, however, this is only a conjecture, based on the current level of financial development. An independent test of this conjecture can be obtained going back in history. Since the choice of the legal system was done, at the latest, during the 19th century, we could try and look at the major indicators of financial development at the beginning of the 20th century and see whether it is still true that Common Law countries are more financially developed.
Answering this question is complicated by data availability. We have data only on a subset of countries in Table 1, and on only a few measures. To triangulate the ”true” measures, we present data coming from different sources.
The first source is Goldsmith (1969), who is the most authoritative source on the history of financial development. He reports some basic statistics for the most developed countries of the time. For comparability, we rearranged them in Table 2.
Column I of Table 2a reports per capita Gross National Product (GNP) in 1913 and column II the ratio of market values of securities outstanding in 1913 to GNP that year. In the definition of security Goldsmith includes both stocks and bonds, without differentiating between bonds of financial institutions and other bonds. This column, then, should be compared with the sum of columns (II) and (III) in Table 1.
The difference in data sources prevents us from drawing any strong conclusion about the difference in levels between 1913 and 1996. Nevertheless, it striking that all the values in 1913 are well above the corresponding 1996 levels. The closest figures are for the United States (1.5 in 1913 vs. 1.14 in 1996), the most dispersed for France (2.5 in 1913 and 0.5 in 1996).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:87 |
|
|
Table 2. Financial Development before WWI
A: Period
|
(I) |
|
(II) |
(III) |
(IV) |
(V) |
(VI) |
|
Per capita |
Securities/ |
|
Adjusted |
|
(Securities + |
|
|
GNP in |
GNP |
Securities/ |
Securities/ |
D Asset Banks |
D Asset Banks)/ |
|
|
1913 |
$ |
in 1913 |
Total GNP |
Total GNP |
Total GNP |
Total GNP |
USA |
406 |
|
1.504 |
0.069 |
0.053 |
0.040 |
0.093 |
Britain |
313 |
|
2.268 |
0.071 |
0.029 |
0.026 |
0.055 |
France |
232 |
|
2.454 |
0.074 |
0.040 |
0.030 |
0.070 |
Germany |
211 |
|
1.533 |
0.063 |
0.030 |
0.061 |
0.091 |
NA |
|
NA |
0.026 |
0.020 |
0.025 |
0.045 |
|
Italy |
143 |
|
0.686 |
0.023 |
0.020 |
0.025 |
0.045 |
Russia |
83 |
|
0.592 |
0.024 |
0.020 |
0.013 |
0.032 |
Japan |
45 |
|
1.308 |
0.067 |
0.062 |
0.022 |
0.084 |
B: Period
|
(I) |
(II) |
(III) |
(IV) |
(V) |
|
Securities |
Domestic |
Shares |
Bond |
(Dom. Sec + |
|
issued/ |
sec. issued/ |
issued/ |
issued/ |
D Asset Banks)/ |
|
Total GNP |
Total GNP |
Total GNP |
Total GNP |
Total GNP |
|
|
|
|
|
|
USA |
0.052 |
0.051 |
0.017 |
0.034 |
0.109 |
Britain |
0.068 |
0.021 |
|
0.021 |
0.050 |
France |
0.072 |
0.037 |
0.022 |
0.015 |
0.073 |
Germany |
0.044 |
0.036 |
0.010 |
0.026 |
0.121 |
Japan |
0.085 |
0.085 |
0.025 |
0.060 |
0.140 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Source: Goldsmith (1969).
We can, however, be more confident about the differences within each period. In 1913 France and England appear the most developed capital markets, with Germany, Japan, and the United States close behind. Italy and Russia are a distant last, in part because of their relative economic underdevelopment. Thus, the initial first mover advantage enjoyed by England seems to have been eliminated. Although the paucity of observations prevents any statistical testing, there seems to be no connection between type of legal system and level of development. In fact, countries with a similar level of economic development (the first four) have similar levels of financial development. The variability within this group is much less pronounced than in 1996. The real outlier appears to be Japan. In spite of its late industrialization, it has a level of financial development comparable to the first four countries.
Unfortunately, for this time period it is difficult to have data on the level of capital formation financed with securities. Since most of the
Volym D:88 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
securities outstanding in 1913 were probably issued in the period 1861- 1913, Goldsmith approximates the securities issued during the period with the securities outstanding at the end of the period. He then normalizes them by the total GNP produced during the period (column III). Since Gross Capital Formation is roughly 20 % of GNP, to make these figures comparable to the one in Table 1 we have to divide them by 0.2 (i.e. to multiply them by 5). After that they should be compared with the last column of Table 1. The 1913 figures appear smaller than the 1996 ones for the United States and the United Kingdom, but much bigger for France and Italy. Since differences in the variable definition can explain more easily an overall difference in the level, not a cross- sectional variation in the difference, this pattern is likely to illustrate a real phenomenon: the importance of securities has grown in some countries, while it has declined in others.
Goldsmith tries to refine his estimate of the amount of corporate securities issued by eliminating bonds of mortgage banks, foreign securities, and an estimate of capital gains from the total value of securities outstanding. The ”adjusted” ratio is reported in column IV.
The importance of security issues drops substantially for France and England, which had a large volume of foreign securities issuance (an issue we will discuss momentarily). The country that seems to have financed most with securities is Japan, followed closely by the United States, with the other developed countries close behind. Italy, Austria, and Russia are, again, far behind. Thus, the adjustment does not substantially modify the conclusions.
Column V we reports the ratio of the increase in bank assets to total GNP produced during the period. Excluding Russia, in all the other countries the increase in bank assets accounts for roughly 2.5 % of the GNP, except for the Unites States (4 %) and Germany (6 %). Thus, while banks appear very important in Germany, the traditional difference between
Following Goldsmith in column VI we sum the adjusted measure of securities issued and the increment in bank assets during the period. This measure is then deflated by the total GNP produced during the period. If the capital to GDP ratio is constant, the ratio in column IV provides a rough idea of what fraction of investment are financed externally. The difference between
Table 2a does not properly distinguish domestic securities from foreign securities and stocks from bonds. Goldsmith provides this information for a subset of countries and a shorter time period. We report this information in Table 2b.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:89 |
|
|
Column I does not look substantially different from column II of Table 2a, in spite of the shorter time period and the different sources (these are actual data on securities issued rather than estimates). Column II reports the same ratio, where as numerator we have only dmestic securities. The difference between columns I and II suggests that London and Paris were the two main international financial centers, with Germany a distant third. Interestingly, the United States exhibits almost no foreign issues of securities.
In principle, the development of a financial system should be measured by its ability to provide cheap finance to industry, not by the actual amount provided. In fact, the actual amount provided is also a function of the demand of external funds by domestic firms. The fact that London and Paris (and to a lesser extent, Berlin) were able to provide more financing than their firms needed is an indication of their advanced level of financial development.
Column III reports the ratio of shares issued divided by the total GNP produced during the period. Japan and France rely most heavily on equity, followed by the United States and then Germany. Again there is no evidence that the equity market is more important in Common Law countries. The difference between columns II and III (reported as column IV) gives us an indication of the importance of the bond market
Finally, column V reports the ratio of the sum of domestic securities issued plus increase of bank assets to GNP produced during the period. Here the ranking seems to be negatively correlated with the period since the beginning of the industrialization process. The United Kingdom, which started first, finances very little of its total production externally – a fact consistent with Gerschenkron (1961). France, United States, Germany, and (at a distance) Japan follow. This result is not necessarily puzzling. The countries that started the industrialization process earlier had more established firms by the beginning of the 20th century, which could finance growth internally.
Goldsmith’s data are gathered from a variety of sources. To validate his main conclusions we followed two alternative routes. First, the League of Nations International Statistical Yearbook has data on equity issues for a small subset of countries starting back in 1913. In Table 3 we report these data deflated by the GDP of that year.37 For ease of comparison we report the same ratio computed in 1996 (data are from the FIBV).
37 Data on GDP are from B.R. Mitchell, International Historical Statistics, Stockton Press.
Volym D:90 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Table 3. Equity issues over GDP
|
1913 |
1996 |
Germany |
0.014 |
0.004 |
Denmark |
0.006 |
0.006 |
United States |
0.047 |
0.029 |
France |
0.053 |
0.015 |
Italy |
0.013 |
0.005 |
Japan |
0.118 |
0.002 |
Netherlands |
0.056 |
0.053 |
UK |
0.017 |
0.017 |
Sweden |
0.055 |
0.009 |
Switzerland |
0.133 |
0.007 |
Sources: League of Nations International Statistical Yearbook, Mitchell, International Historical Statistics, and FIBV.
Before interpreting the data, three caveats are necessary. First, the 1913 datum for the United States is in fact from 1923 (earliest available). Second, the 1913 reported datum for the United Kingdom represents domestic issues only, foreign subscriptions are five times as large. Finally, the 1913 data represent the actual issue value only for the United States, the United Kingdom, Switzerland and Germany. For the other countries they represent the nominal value, which is a lower bound for the issue value. Thus, they would underestimate the true value.
Switzerland and Japan appear as the biggest equity issuers, roughly 12 % of GDP. France, United States, Sweden, and the Netherlands are in second position with roughly 5 % of GDP. Germany, Italy, and United Kingdom are last with roughly 1.5 %. These results seem to confirm the one from Goldsmith reported in column III of Table 2.B. Again, it is very difficult to see a clear difference between Common Law countries and Civil Law countries.
Since the data, albeit collected from different sources, are fairly homogeneous, we can also attempt an intertemporal comparison. The importance of equity issues seems to have dropped dramatically in Japan, Switzerland, France, Sweden, Germany, and Italy. It has remained constant in the United Kingdom, Denmark, and the Netherlands. It has dropped a little in the United States. It is possible that this might reflect only seasonal factors. In Japan, for instance, equity issues have been curtailed in recent years, following a severe drop in the index. If we exclude Japan, the major drop is concentrated in Continental Europe. Is this just a coincidence or a more generalized phenomenon?
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:91 |
|
|
To explore this issue we make use of a third source. We obtained historical stock market capitalization data from Global Financial Data, a company that specializes in collecting historical financial information. It claims to be ”the most extensive, comprehensive collection of financial historical data in the world”. Yet, their coverage of market capitalizations around the world is quite sparse in the earlier part of this century. Data for the United Kingdom starts in 1900, for the United States in 1924, for the major European countries in 1929, for Japan in 1930.38 In addition, we purchased data on stock returns from them, which are much more complete and start from the 1910s. Thus, we can compute the ratio of stock market capitalization to GDP for several countries in 1929. In order to obtain a measure of stock market capitalization for 1913 we extrapolated the data backward for a number of countries in two ways. The first simply takes the earliest datum available and extrapolates it backwards to 1913 using the return of the local stock market index. This estimate is correct if equity issues equal to delisting at every single point in time.
There are biases. Delistings (other than mergers which would have no effect for our purposes) probably take place at very low values of a stock’s capitalization, so they would have relatively minor effect. Issuances take place at high stock market values. So a more conservative estimate is to subtract the League of Nation data on equity issues from the final value of the stock market capitalization before extrapolating the data back using the actual return on the index. If equity issues were typically made when the market was high, we understate capitalization in 1913.
The League of Nation data start for most countries in 1913, but it does not report the information for the years
38Interestingly, for a number of Continental European countries data on stock market capitalization are available before WWII, but not after it until the 1970s. This, by itself, is a good indicator of the drop in importance of the equity market in these economies.
39Because the data on the market capitalization of the Curb Exchange (later Amex) starts only in 1938, in previous years we inflated the value of the NYSE capitalization by the ratio of the value of the Curb and the value of the NYSE in 1938.
Volym D:92 Supplement 24 |
|
|
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
|||
|
|
|
|
|
|||||
|
Table 4. Evolution of Stock Market Capitalization over GDP |
|
|
|
|||||
|
|
1913 (a) |
1913 (b) |
1929 |
1938 |
1948 |
1960 |
1997 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
USA |
0.68 |
0.50 |
0.75 |
0.64 |
0.31 |
0.66 |
1.33 |
|
|
Belgium |
0.79 |
0.06 |
0.43 |
0.60 |
0.27 |
0.37 |
0.57 |
|
|
Bulgaria |
|
|
0.05 |
0.09 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
|
|
|
Canada |
1.22 |
|
1.11 |
0.98 |
0.47 |
1.39 |
0.92 |
|
|
Czech Republic |
|
|
0.11 |
0.15 |
|
|
|
|
|
Denmark |
0.92 |
0.90 |
0.38 |
0.28 |
|
|
0.55 |
|
|
Finland |
0.37 |
|
0.34 |
0.32 |
|
|
0.61 |
|
|
France |
0.66 |
0.27 |
0.43 |
0.22 |
0.12 |
0.27 |
0.49 |
|
|
Germany |
1.93 |
1.34 |
0.29 |
0.17 |
|
|
0.39 |
|
|
Hungary |
0.43 |
|
0.22 |
0.22 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
|
|
|
Italy |
1.71 |
0.42 |
0.32 |
0.29 |
|
|
0.30 |
|
|
Japan |
2.56 |
1.82 |
0.79 |
0.99 |
0.05 |
0.27 |
0.53 |
|
|
Norway |
1.59 |
|
0.22 |
0.20 |
|
|
0.43 |
|
|
Spain |
0.53 |
|
0.33 |
0.42 |
|
|
0.55 |
|
|
Switzerland |
1.75 |
0.97 |
0.63 |
0.63 |
|
|
2.26 |
|
|
United Kingdom |
4.29 |
4.29 |
7.04 |
3.01 |
0.91 |
0.88 |
1.55 |
|
(a)assuming equity issues= delistings
(b)assuming equity issues = data from league of nations and delistings = 0
Sources: Global Financial Data, League of Nations International Statistical Yearbook, Goldsmith (for GDP data).
A few facts are worth noticing. First, the enormous value of the ratio in London. Note that this is not an estimate, but the actual datum. In the U.K. the magnitude of the ratio between stock market capitalization and GDP peaked in 1929, to drop dramatically in later decades. In fact, in 1960 this ratio was only 88 %. It would be useful to keep in mind that this was the period of nationalization in Britain.
Once we take out the United Kingdom, there is no difference between the rest of the countries. In fact, the relative size of the stock market in many European countries exceeds that of the United States.
Although the coverage is not continuous, in Table 4 we can follow the behavior of this indicator through the different decades of this century. Interestingly, all the countries experienced a major drop in the importance of the equity market after WWII. This is not true only of the defeated countries, but also of the victors. Only in the United States did the stock market regain its
The overall results are striking. So striking that one worries they might be a statistical artifact. To eliminate this suspicion it would be useful to have some microeconomic evidence that the effect macro statistics are capturing is indeed real. Such evidence is provided by
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:93 |
|
|
Calomiris (1994). He compares the underwriting costs of new equity issues in Germany and in the United States at the beginning of the century. Underwriting costs can be considered a proxy for the efficiency of capital markets (the smaller the cost, the higher the efficiency). The spread charged by U.S. banks on issues of common equity was about 18 %, while the one charged by German banks was only 5 %. This would also explain why between 1896 and 1913 German firms issues substantially more equity than U.S. firms.
Summary
We started this work noticing the variability of various indicators of financial development across fairly homogenous countries and we asked why such differences existed. We can rule out at least one answer, with all the caveats about not having enough data to perform tests of statistical significance. Differences in the nature of the legal system cannot be directly responsible. The legal system did not change over the decades, so why did the level of financial development? To explain why France and Germany are less financially developed than the United States today, we do not have to look at the distant past. We need to understand what happened in between the two wars, that changed the course of financial history. Having ruled out the other major causes, we are left with only one: politics. This is what we explore next.
Volym D:94 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
6A Political Economy of Financial Development
Given all the benefits of financial development, it is somewhat surprising how few countries in the world have sophisticated financial markets. Clearly, a well developed legal, accounting, and regulatory infrastructure are necessary for a well functioning financial system. Why don’t countries copy more successful models? Fixed costs, while initially important, are not a major impediment in the long run nor, as we have argued, is the nature of the legal system. The impediment, we believe, is to be found through an analysis of the political economy of financial development. In this section, we attempt a simple calculus of consensus à la Buchanan.
The two main players in this analysis are the interest groups and the Government. Interest groups pressure the government to favor them. The nature of the government – whether democratic, oligarchic or a monarchy – will determine which group has more saying and to what extent its wishes get translated into actions. Until the beginning of the 20th centuries governments were at best oligarchic. Thus, the calculus of consensus can be limited to the dominant elite, which had the biggest impact on the government. In the 20th century the analysis is further complicated by the growing influence of the masses.
But the government does not simply reflect the wishes of the dominant interest group, it also has its own agenda. This is clearly the case in a monarchy, but also in a democracy where the entrenched government bureaucracy has its own perks and survival at stake. Thus, asking why some political systems oppose financial development is tantamount to asking why some influential groups or the Government (or both) oppose financial development.
6.1Why the Dominant Elite May Oppose Financial Development?
To illustrate in a simple way the various political forces at work, we assume that there exists a magic law able to eliminate all the imperfections present in a real world financial market, transforming it into a
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:95 |
|
|
study, in a highly stylized framework, who will gain and who will lose by an improvement in financial markets and, thus, identify supporters and opponents of financial development. It will also identify when this opposition is more likely to be successful and what forms it might take.
One of the main consequences of the approval of our hypothetical law will be a reduction in the rents from the ownership of current resources; In an imperfect world , some
Thus, the approval of our hypothetical law will have two main distributional effects. First, people with an initial endowment of resources, whom we will call the rich (or equally, the
Another distributional consequence of the approval of our hypothetical magic law would be the loss in value of reputation. In a perfect capital market, i.e. a market with perfect disclosure and perfect enforcement, reputation is worthless. By contrast, in a world with no disclosure and no enforcement, investors will have to rely exclusively on the reputation of the issuer. Thus reputation, very much like the initial endowment, becomes necessary to start any economic activity. But reputation is something that takes time to accumulate, cannot be purchased, and can be transferred to others only with difficulty. Since the rich or
Capital markets also tend to point out inefficiencies and cross- subsidies, and increase the risk that underperformance will be penalized. Moreover, they are brutal in that they do not recognize past investment or favors unless explicitly contracted for. If contracting is imperfect, those who are likely to underperform, or legitimately fear the risk that they might underperform, will lose from financial development.
Of course, a perfect capital market increases the availability of funds for profitable projects and it improves the return on capital invested. These benefits occur to everybody. Thus, the extent of opposition depends on whether the share of benefits a particular group can appropriate is sufficiently large to compensate for the losses suffered.
Volym D:96 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
For example, if the rich have become so because they had ideas in the past, and will continue to have them in the future, the benefit produced by an increase in the number of projects they can undertake will more than compensate for the reduction in the value of their initial endowment. By contrast, if the rich made their money in the past through passive ownership of resources such as land, the loss they suffer in the value of their endowment and reputation may dominate any gains. In other words, an economy dominated by self made entrepreneurs is likely to push more for financial development than an economy dominated by the landed gentry.
6.2Financial Markets and the Government
The development of financial markets affects the government’s own agenda. On the one hand, it makes it easier for the government to raise financing. On the other, it creates private sector competition for the funds of citizens and foreigners, which may reduce the government’s share or increase its cost of funding. Some governments may find it better to keep the market underdeveloped so that citizens have no option but to park their funds with it (or its agents).
Of course, the system of government affects its willingness and ability to intervene. A centralized power is the biggest impediment to financial development. When the property rights of citizens are not well developed, strong governments cannot commit not to expropriate. Almost by definition, financial markets and institutions tend to concentrate a lot of wealth in one place. In so doing they make it easy for the Government to grab resources at a very low cost (or, in more modern terms, to collect taxes at a low cost).40 Of course, the Government incentive to expropriate the financiers depends crucially on who the financiers are and who controls the Government. A monarch supported by the landed aristocracy typically found irresistible the temptation to expropriate the financiers from the city, especially the foreign Lombards and the Jews. By contrast, law bound (and weaker) 41Governments cannot expropriate, allowing finance to flourish.
Even when naked expropriation is not possible, one cannot escape the fact that powerful centralized governments usually have agendas. Free
40See Myers and Rajan (1998).
41This shows the power of
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:97 |
|
|
markets typically have only one agenda, to make money. It is always tempting for the government to alter the rules of the market so as to direct the resources of the market in a favorable direction, rather than pay the appropriate price. This is especially true when the government faces an outside threat to its survival – when it wants to transform the entire economy into a command and control system because that, rather than uncoordinated markets is the quickest way to mobilize resources. The long term damage to markets can, of course, be considerable. For example, centralized power has an incentive to create oligopolistic banking systems to replace financial markets, because these can be persuaded with favors and threats unlike an arm’s length market. Moreover, once created, hierarchies are concentrations of power, and unlike dispersed markets, can coordinate to oppose change.
Markets also require and create a high degree of transparency, which can highlight the inefficiency of the actions of centralized power. This is inconvenient, especially in a democracy (democracies, of course, can be centralized).
Finally, centralized power might undertake activities that would otherwise be undertaken in the private sector and further the development of markets. For example, a railway system became imperative for a country’s infrastructure during the 19th century. As already mentioned, this spurred the rise of financial markets in the United States. In many Continental European countries, however, the fear the private sector would lag behind in railway construction lead to direct Government intervention. By directly financing the construction of railways, the Governments may have overcome the short term disability created by inadequate private financial markets, but unwittingly prevented the emergence of private institutions that would have found railway financing a good way to overcome fixed
42 Santos (1998).
Volym D:98 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
6.3Interaction Between Politics and the Law
Even if the nature of the interest groups that hold political power at the center or the Government own agenda are the primary determinants of financial development, the legal system can play an important role, by affecting the influence these groups have. In particular, there are several reasons why the Common Law system can better resist the political pressure against financial development.
First, the English common law tradition emphasizes restraining the government and protecting the individual, making more difficult for the Government to interfere with private property. Thus, in the early stages of financial development, Common Law helps protect the rights of the individual against the state, and hence fostered the development of private finance.
Second, Common Law evolves at the periphery, and innovates around legislative or administrative roadblocks set up by the center. In England, for instance, in 1720 an act of legislation (the Bubble Act) placed constraints on the incorporation of limited liability companies. Common law courts, however, made their own judgement as to which companies did not contravene the spirit of that law. Thus, the decentralized nature of decision making enables Common Law countries to overcome the
Finally, Common Law is based primarily on judicial precedent, rather than upon the act of a legislator. Thus, a new political climate is less able to transform the structure of the law. For example, Roosevelt’s attempt to cartelize the U.S. economy failed not because of political opposition, but because of the resistance of the U.S. Supreme Court, which struck down several key pieces of the New Deal legislation. In Continental European and in Japan Governments did not find such resistance and successfully cartelized many sectors, starting from the banking one.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:99 |
|
|
7 Back to History
In the previous section we concluded that there are two important factors determining the likelihood of financial development: the calculus of its costs and benefits for the different political constituencies and the power and centralization of Government. In what follows we undertake a brief historical analysis of the conditions surrounding the emergence of major financial centers to verify whether they are broadly consistent with the predictions we highlighted.
7.1Early Financial Centers
Till the late middle ages, the dominant elite in many European countries were the landed aristocracy. Traditionally, farming was a very low- capital intensity business, but for the cost of the land itself. The aristocracy inherited the land or received it from the Crown, in return for which it met its feudal obligations. There was little to benefit from a financial system; Trade was considered degrading (itself evidence of a cultural bias against new comers), and most wealth was embodied in land, which generated little investible surplus. However, the aristocracy had a lot to lose from financial development. First, the emergence of a merchant class could jeopardize its political domination. Second, the ease of access to external funds in the absence of profitable investment opportunities could translate into a surge of luxury consumption by the young nobles eventually leading some aristocratic families losing their land. This would have lead to a separation between land ownership and nobility, which could undermine the stability in the ruling elite. The desire to prevent such disruption can explain why, in a society dominated by nobles, it was so difficult, if not impossible, for the nobles to sell their land.
Contrast this with Venice, the epitome of the Italian
Volym D:100 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
form of limited partnership, is also the most direct ancestor of the modern joint stock company. Venetian Public Debt was bought by foreigners, drawn by Venice’s reputation for servicing it through thick and thin – in fact, Venice’s Monte Vecchio served as the equivalent of Swiss Banks of our time, holding funds with no questions asked.
It is also not coincidental that power in Venice was surprisingly widely distributed among the citizenry, considering the times. Venice was a republic with checks and balances on the power of its government. Its executive, legislature, and judiciary, right up to the Doge, were elected, and except for the Doge who was a life appointee, held tenure for only a short time. The short tenure not only protected against incipient dictatorship, it also ensured that all eligible citizens got a turn at governance. There was always a strong chance that the roles would be reversed in the near future when a supplicant faced an official. This implied that governance, at least for eligible citizens (approximately one fortieth of the entire population) was likely to be fair. As insurance, those that displayed dictatorial tendencies while in office were often banished.
Consistent with the political theory, all the early financial centers of the Modern world, starting with Florence and Venice, going on to Hamburg and the cities of the Hanseatic League, and culminating in Amsterdam, emerged in little independent political entities controlled by the bourgeoisie (bourgeois literally means inhabitant of the city). The bourgeois was not a landlord but a craftsman or a merchant, who needed access to external funds to finance his working capital. By contrast, none of the political centers of big and powerful centralized states (Paris, Madrid, or Vienna) emerged as important financial centers.
7.2The Emergence of London
England was the first of the large nation states to have a well developed financial system, and London was at the center of it. How did London emerge as a financial center in the 17th and 18th centuries? In part, it was the devastation produced by the two
In England, as in most other Nation States at that time, the dominant elite was the landed aristocracy (gentry). But unlike other States, the English landed aristocracy in the 17th century could benefit from a development of the capital markets. The agricultural revolution, started
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:101 |
|
|
by the enclosure movement, transformed British agriculture into more of a business. And as a modern business, British agriculture required capital and generated a surplus that could be invested. Thus, British aristocracy, unlike aristocracy elsewhere, had valuable opportunities to invest extra funds and, after the initial ”dividends”, more funds to be reinvested in the capital market. This made it better disposed towards the development of a financial system. One should also not understate the strength of the mercantile constituency, fortified by England’s maritime prowess.
At the same time, financial development was facilitated by the weakness of the British Crown. The Glorious Revolution of 1688, which put William and Mary on the throne, also forced them to agree to a Declaration of Rights. By doing so, the Crown recognized the legislative supremacy of Parliament and also the necessity of parliamentary consent for a standing army in peacetime. Given that Parliament represented both the moneyed interests of merchants and financiers (the Whigs) and the landed gentry (the Tories), it was clear that property and financial contracts would be much more secure against the depredations of the Crown. Equally important, without a standing army, the Crown had no way of imposing its wishes on Parliament. Finally, the existence of an independent judiciary enforcing common law further strengthened the hands of public creditors against the Crown. As political economists Douglass North and Barry Weingast argue, the credible commitment not to interfere with property rights led to the development of government finance. So, somewhat paradoxically, as sociologist Bruce Carruthers argues, the internal weakness of the English Crown allowed it to raise large sums at short notice, giving it external strength and transforming England into a first rate European power.
It did, however, take time for the English Crown to gain credibility, even after the Glorious Revolution, especially because of previous events such as the Stop on the Exchequer, when Charles II suspended debt payments amounting to about $ 1.3 million pounds (at a time when annual Crown income was less than 2 million pounds).43 Therefore, much of its initial funding was not direct but through large companies, prominent among which were the Bank of England, the East India Company, and the South Sea Company. By 1712, these three companies had loaned 15.8 million pounds to the government, which was approximately 62 percent of the funded debt.44
Each of these companies was granted a monopoly, which, in effect, was an indirect tax on the people. The Bank of England had a monopoly
43Carruthers, p. 122.
44Carruthers, p. 155.
Volym D:102 Supplement 24 SOU 2000:11
over note issue, the East India company had a monopoly of trade with the Indies, and the South Sea Company obtained the monopoly over trade with the South Seas (a monopoly which turned out later to be of little value). In order to secure and preserve these monopolies, the companies repeatedly loaned money to the Crown. Thus the early joint stock company was set up, in part, as a device for the Crown to transform future monopoly rents into current funding. Since the shareholders of these companies were many, and included many prominent members of Parliament, the commitment made by the Crown (with the acquiescence of Parliament) to the companies was secure.
While shareholders of the companies knew that they were secure from government expropriation, it was less clear that the management of the companies could not fiddle with the accounts or otherwise exploit investors. The absence of corporate governance would surely have hurt the companies' ability to raise money from investors, and thus also hurt the government, which depended so much for funding from these companies. Therefore, it was in the interests of the government to ensure the public investor was protected. Moreover, the companies were so intertwined in politics that it was almost inevitable their governance would resemble the emerging democratic political process. This was especially so because the two strong competing political parties each wanted a share of the power and patronage that came with control over the companies.
As a result, early corporate charters, to which the Government had to give its assent, ensured that the directors of the Bank of England and the East India Company were elected. Even though voting was restricted to those who had a substantial stake – the East India Company allowed only those with over 500 pounds in shares to vote – the election of directors was a serious event, and trading at the time of the election of directors was active, and especially so in blocks over 500 pounds.45
The negative influence that a strong government can have on corporate governance can also be seen in some periods of British History. After unsuccessful attempts at gaining control through elections over the Bank of England and the East India Company in
45 Carruthers, p. 151.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:103 |
|
|
antagonize the Whig moneyed interests because they were the primary source of funding, so some investor protections were built in. The point, however, is to suggest that the initial fortuitous political climate in England, as well as the need for government finance, led eventually to the development of governance of joint stock companies.
7.3The French Experience
As the political scientist and historian, Samuel Finer puts it, ”the four great differences between the absolutism of the king of France [in the seventeenth century], and the relative limitation of the English monarchy were…that the former could strike taxes and make laws at pleasure and was served by a standing army and paid professional bureaucracy”. There was a consistency in these powers. The King could levy new taxes, which the bureaucracy would collect, with the threat of the standing army always in the background to enforce payments. Taxes, though, take time to levy and collect, especially when the bureaucracy is as inefficient as the French then was. Thus the Crown had to borrow to finance wartime expenditure. A number of economists and historians have argued that the immense power of the French Crown, and its past record of defaults, prevented it from raising loans directly from the public. Furthermore, it was impossible to protect investor rights because of the unlimited personal authority of the king.
Instead, the French Crown raised money at short notice in two ways. First, it borrowed through lesser state bodies such as the Hotel de Ville de Paris. The advantage of borrowing through these lesser state bodies is that, unlike the king, they could be sued in court.46 Of course, since the King ultimately also had power over the courts, this turned out to be a protection of doubtful value. Second, the sale of venal offices was another source of funding. The purchaser paid for the office up front, and made additional investments down the line to acquire additional powers. In return, the government paid an annual interest, and conferred status (occasionally, minor nobility) on the purchaser. In the 1660s, forty six thousand offices had been sold (with many offices being split over time as the need for new funding arose) for an amount approximating four to five times the annual revenue of the crown. Of course, there was no requirement that the purchaser be qualified for the
46 More valuable was the right that if a city failed in its obligations to a creditor, the creditor could take actions against the person and property of any citizen of that city who fell in his power. Thus cities that traded a lot obtained the ability to borrow by giving creditors this extreme power.
Volym D:104 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
office, and since many of these offices included actual duties such as collecting taxes or serving as magistrate, the efficiency of administration fell over time. Nevertheless, unlike loans to the crown, the offices carried their own security since the Crown could not do away with them with destroying a substantial part of the administrative machinery.
The French Revolution did not change matters much because, while power was taken away from the crown, it was concentrated again in the central government. The French did not have a true parliamentary democracy until the constitution of the Third Republic was passed in 1875.47 It is useful to see the effects on two major components of a modern economy – limited liability corporations and the banking system. For reasons of space, our description will only be a sketch.
The legal forms of business organization permitted by the French Civil Code of 1807 were simple partnerships, limited partnerships in which only the active partners had unlimited liability, and true joint stock or limited liability companies. In order to incorporate as a limited liability company, a firm needed special permission from the Council of State. This body granted charters sparingly, and usually only to industries it deemed in the public interest.48 It was not until the depression of 1857, and under pressure from the now strong industrial interests that the state was persuaded of the greater resilience of limited liability companies, and passed laws in 1863 and 1867 that allowed free incorporation.
Contrast this with the developments in England. While the Bubble Act of 1720 did place constraints on the incorporation of limited liability companies, common law courts made their own judgement as to which companies did not contravene the spirit of that law. So, for example, in 1811, the issue of widely held, and transferable, common stock by an unincorporated bread manufacturer was deemed to be legal.49 Since allowing the transfer of a stock essentially implied that its previous owner could not be held liable for the firm's debts, this judgement allowed limited liability for a venture if its intent seemed honorable. Therefore, even though the Bubble Act was repealed only in 1825, and companies could get limited liability without the necessity of a charter from the government in 1855, common law allowed many of the trappings of limited liability to corporations much before then.
There are two important points to reiterate from this discussion. First, common law allowed more legal and financial innovation (for example, in corporate form). Second, the civil code could speedily adopt
47Finer, p.
48Cameron, p. 112.
49Powell, p. 178.
SOU 2000:11 Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:105
innovations that emerged under the common law system when it so desired. It took over a century and a half for the common law system to work out the limited liability form to its satisfaction in 1855, and at the risk of some understatement, only about a decade for the French civil code to adopt the main outlines of this legal innovation.
This then reinforces our claim that the greater ability to innovate is, by itself, not the reason the common law system fosters financial development. Instead, it is partly the ability of the decentralized common law system to innovate around the political impediments placed by the center that enable it to foster financial development. By contrast, in civil law countries, the centralized control of the legislative process ensures that the powers that be can stand in the way of anything against their interests.
To illustrate this point, consider the differences between the broad actions of the Bank of France and those of the Bank of England. After Napoleon came to power, he sought a ready source of credit. Given the success of the Bank of England in mobilizing credit for the English government, a bank seemed a natural device. The Bank of France was capitalized at 30 million francs, but unlike the Bank of England, had ”difficulty placing its shares in spite of the personal example of the First Consul and his decree requiring government agents to purchase shares and deposit their surplus funds in the Bank; almost two years elapsed before the entire capital was paid in”. 50
The Bank of France was little more than an extension of the government (perhaps indicating why it had difficulty raising capital), and it had extensive demands made on it. With the fall of the Empire in 1814, the Bank went into virtual liquidation. While there were some moves to privatize the Bank at this point, the Restoration government felt it was too valuable a resource to lose. As Baron Louis, the then Finance minister told the representatives of the Bank ”You want to be independent, but you will not; you will have a governor, I will name him, and he will not be the one who currently occupies the post”. 51
Between 1800 and 1848, the Bank of France stood as a bulwark against financial development because competition threatened its position.52 The Bank opposed the setting up of joint stock banks. It initially resisted setting up its own branches in other cities, and did so only the cities started setting up competing establishments. But having determined to expand outside Paris, it quickly got the government to refuse to charter any new banks. It also took advantage of crisis to take
50Cameron, p. 102.
51Cameron, p. 103.
52Cameron, p.
Volym D:106 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
over competing note issuing banks (obviously with government support) so that in 1848, its monopoly over note issue extended over the whole of France. Interestingly, it was only after the Revolution of 1848 that financial development resumed. Again the reason was political. As economic historian, Rondo Cameron puts it, ”the characteristic institution of the Second Empire, the Societe Generale de Credit Mobilier, also came into existence in 1852 as a part of the government's attempt to provide a counterweight to the influence of the Bank of France and the financiers of the haute banque, most of whom were hostile or at best lukewarm to the new regime”. Finally, even though the monopoly of the Bank of France was slowly whittled down, it had lasting effects. As Cameron argues,
”this failure [to reorganize the commercial banking system], which affected even large enterprises…was especially serious for the numerous small industrialists who could not interest the great bankers in their enterprises or, if they could, feared loss of control and independence…Thus resulted the schizophrenic development of French industry and commerce, traces of which can still be seen today: on the one hand a highly capitalized, technically efficient and progressive sector, on the other a sector composed of small firms, undercapitalized, traditional but tenacious.”
The contrast with England is striking. While the Bank of England had similarly tried to protect its privileges against encroachment, it was far less successful because it was a private entity, because it was in the interests of the Tories to see its powers contested, and because the common law system allowed alternatives like the country banks to emerge. As a result, there was far more competition in financial services, with attendant benefits to industry.
7.4British and Spanish colonies
The differing degree of centralization and the nature of the powerful elite can also explain why the financial development of British colonies today appears so much greater than those of former Spanish colonies. As historian Samuel Finer argues, the English were either escaping religious or political persecution, or trying to improve their lot. They immigrated in entire communities, with people from every social strata and skills represented. A goodly portion represented
SOU 2000:11 Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:107
The English colonies also benefited from a weak and decentralized Government. Their political system reflected the tension between Crown and Parliament, leaning to the Parliamentary side. The colonies were certainly the Dominions of the Crown, and yet not one colony lacked a legislature whose minimalist function was to set taxes.53 In fact, some colonies were essentially joint stock corporations, with the original Massachusetts charter providing that the Governor and his eighteen assistants had to be elected annually by the stockholders and furthermore, requiring quarterly meetings of the entire body. The English government essentially viewed the Empire as a huge trading organization, and interfered with the activities of the colonies only in so far as it affected trade.54
The Spanish colonies were quite different. The Spanish immigrants were ”…for the most part, adventurers, soldiers and officials, in short, a ruling stratum”. 55 Their purpose was largely extractive. As Adam Smith puts it 56
”It was the sacred thirst of gold that carried Oieda, Nicuessa, and Vasco Nugnes de Balboa [to America]. Whenever those adventurers arrived upon an unknown coast, their first enquiry was always if there was any gold to be found there; and according to the information they received concerning this particular, they determined either to quit the country or to settle in it.”
The prospect of uncountable wealth implied that the Spanish Crown always had a strong interest in its colonies. Spanish colonies were organized as hierarchies directly under the control of Castile. All important decisions, as well as many unimportant ones, were made in Spain, and a stream of rules and laws flowed to the colonies with the purpose of binding and guiding the administration.
The Spanish, therefore, transported their hierarchical system and their aristocracy (at least the attitude and mentality of their aristocracy) to the colonies. The deficiencies of the centralized system that we have referred to earlier, again demonstrated itself. Adam Smith, with typical understatement, writes57
53Finer, p. 1383.
54Finer, p. 1399.
55Finer, p. 1382.
56Smith, Book IV, Chpt VII, p. 73.
57Smith, Book IV, Chpt VII, p. 79.
Volym D:108 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
”The Spanish colonies, therefore, from the moment of their first establishment, attracted very much the attention of their mother country; while those of the other European nations were for a long time in a great measure neglected. The former did not, perhaps, thrive the better in consequence of this attention; nor the latter the worse in consequence of this neglect.”
And later,58
”There is more equality, therefore, among the English colonists than among the inhabitants of the mother country. Their manners are more republican… The absolute governments of Spain, Portugal, and France, on the contrary, take place in their colonies; and the discretionary powers which such governments commonly delegate to all their inferior officers are, on account of the great distance, naturally exercised there with more than ordinary violence.”
Thus the English colonies were set up in such a manner as to facilitate the political forces leading to financial development. By contrast, the colonies of Spain (and France) accentuated the forces that served to hinder financial development.
7.5The Contrast with the Netherlands
An interesting, middle of the road, example is represented by the Netherlands. The Union of Utrecht in 1579 created a decentralized structure where the members of the States General, the national parliament, were selected by the different provinces. Delegates had to refer back to their respective provincial assemblies often for instructions.59 Even though the Dutch was one of the most heavily taxed people, the United Provinces did not have a centralized tax system. Money was raised at the provincial level and then funneled to the center. Each province had a quota, and extraordinary wartime expenditures were appropriately shared. Large and sudden expenditures were financed through public borrowing.
The Dutch government, unlike the English Crown, established a reputation for servicing its debts quite early. In part, this was because the democratic tradition emerged earlier, allowing political curbs to be placed on the powers of the government. Since government debt was widely held (around 1670, the Dutch Mercury stated that in the province of Holland alone, there were 65,500 persons who had or were able to invest money in annuities), much of it by the ruling elite, there was little
58Smith, Book IV, Chpt VII, p.
59Carruthers, p. 103.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:109 |
|
|
chance that the government would willingly default on its debt.60 In fact, ”investment in home securities was so popular that it was often considered a favor to be allowed to invest in them; and repayment was a source of regret and even called forth tearful remonstrances from creditors, because in no other place could money be put out so quickly and safely”. 61
Contrast this reputation with that of the English Crown before the Glorious Revolution. It is no wonder that the Dutch government could borrow at an interest rate of 4 percent while Charles II had to pay up to 12 percent on his borrowing.62 Even after the Glorious Revolution, the English Crown had to establish a reputation for repayment, and convince investors that their power to secure repayment was adequate, before it could borrow large long term funds directly from the public. As a result, it had to rely substantially on the
So both in England and the Dutch Republic financial development could take off because the elite wanted it and power was decentralized. The major difference between the two countries was in the political strength of the two Governments. The English Government, caught in the struggle between the Crown and Parliament, was politically weak. The Dutch Republic, instead, could count on a strong popular base. Thus, it had no need/incentive to favor the formation of investor friendly corporations. A second difference was that even though the Dutch parliament was indirectly elected, it was firmly under the control of the provinces, and by extension, influential investors. This then seemed to be an adequate means of governing the Dutch East India Company (also known as the VOC), the largest and most famous of the Dutch joint stock firms. Operating control of the VOC was vested in 17 active directors, 8 of whom were nominated by Amsterdam, 8 by the other large provinces, and one directorship rotated among the smaller provinces. In short, since the state enjoyed the confidence of the public (at least, the influential among them), there seemed little need for a separate governance structure for corporations. Shares had no voting rights, and trading was especially active at dividend time, in contrast to the English common stock companies where trade was especially
60Carruthers, p.
61Ehrenberg, p. 350.
62Carruthers, p. 60.
63De Vries, p. 153.
Volym D:110 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
important at the time of election of new directors.64 Because of the greater credibility of Dutch public governance, independent corporate governance did not develop in the Dutch Republic to the extent that it did in England.
7.6The Triumph of the Bourgeoisie
On the basis of the historical account so far it is hard to separate the influence of the legal system and that of politics. As Cameron puts it, ”Fortunately for England, the law was sufficiently loose and its administration sufficiently lax that the obstacles to innovation were not insurmountable”. 65 So was it the law or was it politics? Only the subsequent events of the 19th century provide us with a chance to disentangle the two effects. During the 19th century the opportunities provided by the Industrial revolution made it extremely costly not to have an efficient financial system. At the same time, various Revolutions brought the bourgeoisie in power in most countries in Europe. In fact, according to Marx (1848), governments became business committees of the bourgeoisie. Thus, by looking at the level of financial development of the most important developed countries at the turn of the century we can distinguish the two hypotheses. If the main explanatory variable is the legal system, then countries with a common law system should stand out for their level of financial development. By contrast, if politics is important, then all developed countries should have a similar level of financial development.
The evidence reviewed in Section 6 is supportive of the latter interpretation. Besides England, which, thanks to the early move, continued enjoying the benefits of being the financial capital of the world, all other developed countries had a similar level of financial development. Interestingly, many countries that today had underdeveloped markets, back then had very flourishing markets. Thus, a persistent variable, like the nature of the legal system, cannot by itself explain the retreat of the market. It can, however, if coupled with a change in the political environment. This is what we are going to explain next.
64Neale, p. 9.
65Cameron, p. 59.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:111 |
|
|
8 The Reaction
World War I and its aftermath changed everything. As Table 4 shows, financial markets declined significantly in many countries between 1913 and 1948 even as a proportion of GDP, and in some cases have not reverted back to their prewar level even today. What happened?
That World War I was a great disequilibrating event is probably an understatement. Apart from changing the map of Europe, and destroying the people’s faith that their rulers knew what they were doing, the long war accentuated the centralization of many of the economies of Continental Europe. McNeill (1981, p. 339) describes Germany after the implementation of the ”Hindenberg Plan” of 1916 thus
”…the generals in charge often became impatient with the financial claims and controversies that continually embroiled and sometimes obstructed prompt and deferential obedience to their demands. As shortages rose, one after another, the generals relied more and more on big labor and big business to remodel the economy according to military needs. Each party got more or less what it wanted: more munitions for the army, more profits for the industrialists, and consolidation of their authority over the work force for union officials.”
In other words, the economy was being run like a centralized hierarchy model along the lines of the army. Centralization was aided by cartelization – of industry, of the banking sector, and of the work force – because this reduced the number of parties the central authority had to negotiate with. Prices were fixed, and distortions built up in other sectors, especially agriculture, which finally led to Germany’s surrender.66 But the aim of maximizing military production was served, and the costs papered over by blaming the
The centralization during the war thus created large domestic hierarchies representing different interest groups, all of which had acquired power when shielded from international markets and competition. By contrast, the groups that would naturally support markets and competition were suppressed and weakened by the relative
66 McNeill, p.
Volym D:112 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
autarky forced by the long war. The
Centralization also created large distortions that had to be reversed if countries were to go back to the market economies of the prewar era. Prices and wages had to adjust, especially if a country were to go back to the Gold Standard, industries that had prospered during
Thus the groups that had benefited most from the recent past had to adjust the most – a situation typical of economies in transition. Nevertheless, some countries went back to the market quite easily. In particular, the United States did not have to depart too much from the market during the war, and also benefited from the enormous purchases made by the Allies, as well as from servicing the export markets the warring parties had abandoned.
Others such as Britain emerged with deficits, debts, and inflation. A mistaken attempt by Britain to go back to the Gold Standard at prewar parities led to further downward pressure on wages and led to the General Strike of 1926. Germany was in an even worse situation because it was saddled with war reparations that could simply not be met. Despite the difficulties of adjustment, however, the prewar liberal consensus was strong enough, as well as the prospects of international trade attractive enough for virtually the entire industrialized world to be on the Gold Standard again by 1927.67
But as suggested above, the war had changed the power structure in country after country. Strong interest groups ranging from labor to
As Eichengreen (1996) suggests, perhaps in order to discourage speculation in the stock market, the Federal Reserve raised interest rates in the United States in the first half of 1928. Lending to foreign countries by the United States plummeted to zero in the second half of 1928, Eichengreen (1996, p. 71). In order to stay on the Gold Standard, countries had to either eliminate deficits or raise interest rates and contract credit, both politically painful policies. The stock market crash of 1929 in the United States and the ensuing Great Depression was the
67 Eichengreen (1996, p. 48).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:113 |
|
|
proverbial straw. With the single biggest consumer in the world contracting, exports plunged all around the world, further aggravating balance of payment problems in Europe, Japan, and Latin America. Domestic price deflation was necessary to stay on the Gold Standard, and to generate the surpluses to repay debt, but one country’s deflation was simply a contraction of the export markets for another country.
Moreover, as prices fell, with domestic debt largely nominal, defaults increased. Losses at financial institutions increased, and the threat of a financial crisis put pressure on central banks to intervene and bail out the system. Again, under the Gold Standard, central banks could simply not lend freely to bail out the banking system without jeopardizing the exchange rate.
With domestic demands for insurance and subsidies increasing, there was increasing pressure for governments to ”do something”. One of the most attractive features of the Gold Standard was that it allowed governments to finance their deficits by borrowing abroad. In fact, for significant periods in the decades preceding 1913, current account deficits exceeded 10 percent of GDP in Australia, Canada, and Argentina, while in the surplus countries of Britain, France, Germany and Netherlands, net capital outflows touched 9 percent.68 With international lending virtually negligible, even this incentive to adhere to the Gold Standard disappeared.
Thus with export markets moribund, and no possibilities of borrowing, the constituencies in favor of adhering to the Gold Standard were weakened, and country after country abandoned it. A natural consequence was the external discipline on subsidies and distortions was removed and a number of measures mitigating the effects of the markets
– erecting tariff barriers, providing unemployment subsidies, providing subsidized credit, bailing out unviable institutions, increasing government investment – were put in place. The command and control structure only recently disbanded after the war provided an attractive template. In general, the return to the centralized ”political management that had been first explored during World War 1 became unmistakable by the mid 1930s”. 69
This top down grab for power was extremely dangerous in the case of some countries that harbored unsettled grievances from the past. In particular, Germany, Italy and Japan started rearming. These powers had even less interest in maintaining the existence economic order, Germany in particular because of its large reparation dues. As Polanyi (1944, p.
68Bordo, Eichengreenand Irwin (1999, p. 28).
69McNeill, p. 346.
Volym D:114 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
”Germany was now eager to hasten the downfall of traditional world economy, which still provided international order with a foothold, and she anticipated the collapse of that economy, so as to have the start of her opponents. She deliberately cut loose from the international system of capital, commodity and currency so as to lessen the hold of the outer world upon her when she would deem it convenient to repudiate her political obligations. She fostered economic autarchy to ensure the freedom required for her far reaching plans. She squandered her gold reserves, destroyed her foreign credit by gratuitous repudiation of her obligations and even, for a time wiped out her favorable trade balance...”
The command economies of these rogue countries could therefore direct resources effectively towards military
Markets and centralized power are, in general, incompatible. Markets dance to their own tune, and therefore are not responsive to the dictates of centralized power, especially if unaccompanied by monetary reward. By contrast, centralized power wants to mould the economy in its own image as a hierarchy, so that prices and competition do not interfere with the furtherance of its own agenda. The popular groundswell for insurance, the escape from international discipline, and now the need to focus resources on rearmament further strengthened the legitimacy of centralized power. Instead of merely mitigating the adverse effects of the market, it now worked to narrow its sphere and expand the sphere of hierarchies.
In Japan, for example, this implied favoring financial institutions over arm’s length markets. In 1929, Japanese firms raised 26 percent of their debt from bond markets, and only 17 percent from banks. After Japan went off the Gold Standard in December 1931 and intervention in markets increased, the banks with the acquiescence of the Ministry of Finance, formed a Bond Committee in 1933 which determined which firms could issue bonds, on what terms, and when. All bonds were required to be collateralized, and banks were to serve as ”trustees” for the collateral in exchange for a substantial fee. Giving banks the responsibility for determining firms' right to access the public bond markets was like giving a fox who resided in a chicken coop the right to determine which chickens could leave. The obvious outcome was that a flourishing bond market was killed off. By 1936, bonds were down to 14 percent while bank debt was up to 24 percent of liabilities. By 1943, 47 percent of liabilities were bank debt while only 6 percent were bonds.70
70 These figures are from Teranishi (1994).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:115 |
|
|
Moreover, the number of banks declined dramatically over this period as banks were (often forcibly) merged to eliminate ”inefficient” competition. In the span of a few years, the banking system had become much less competitive, and competition from the bond markets was eliminated. And as the country moved towards war, the banking system came under the administrative control of the government.
More generally, the market does not occur naturally, but is a man- made institution, in need of rules and protection as Polanyi (1944) argues. Unfortunately, there is no focussed constituency for the defense of markets, especially in bad times. In particular the very competitive nature of the market that makes it hard to effect
Moreover, once a country walls itself off, the outside world has to be very attractive before it opens up again. Unlike markets, entrenched hierarchies have the power to defend themselves. So the market can be in retreat for a long time. Consider Japan again. Once the banks had power, they were unlikely to give it up easily. Despite their best efforts to break up the bank firm combines established during the period of militarization, the
The intensity of the
Volym D:116 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
an instrument of the State in expanding its power.71 Thus, the new political objectives, be they a stronger military or a more substantial redistribution of resources, could easily permeate the legal infrastructure of these countries. The most extreme example is Romania, where the communist government that took power after WWII found no need to change the Napoleon Code, because it could be easily adapted with minor changes to the new regime. Not only did the
Common Law provided a stronger bulwark against centralization. First, the English common law tradition was shaped by the struggle between the Crown and the aristocracy. As a result, it emphasizes restraining the government and protecting the individual, making more difficult the centralization of the economy. For example, during the First World War, while France and Germany became command and control economies to facilitate military production, England still retained the spirit of voluntarism in war production, see McNeill (1981, p.
It is always dangerous to try to reduce the richness and complexity of the historical evolution of many countries to one single factor. Obviously, many other concurrent events played a role in the extent of the success of the
71 Finer (1997).
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:117 |
|
|
We can, however, offer some support to our thesis that the centralization of the legal system makes it vulnerable to political pressure. Such a test is provided by a recent comparative study of the evolution of U.S. and U.K. bankruptcy procedures.72 Both these countries are based on Common Law. The U.S. Constitution, however, left the right to regulate bankruptcy to the Federal Government, an exception to a system where all corporate governance rules are decided at a state level. The British system has no such provision. This represents the perfect natural experiment of our claim that legal centralization itself leads to greater political interference: two initially identical systems that evolved in similar environments, but which differ mainly in the degree of centralization of the legislative process. Over the years the U.S. bankruptcy procedures departed significantly from its British counterpart, which remained substantially unchanged. Consistent with our claim, these deviations introduced a prodebtor bias, in response to political pressure in that direction.
Conclusions
Our brief review of the historical evolution of financial markets seems consistent with the predictions of the political theory. The reason why at the beginning of the 19th century England emerged as the financial center had primarily to do with its political situation. A fortuitous combination of a dominant elite who could benefit from financial development and a weak and decentralized government that could not interfere (and actually had an interest in promoting development so as to be able to finance itself) lead to the growth in the financial market. The subsequent retreat of markets was due to a convergence of
The analysis also suggests that while a Common law system protects a market economy, it is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for a successful financial market. Instead, our analysis emphasizes the importance that political consensus (or lack of) plays in the development and defense of markets in general and financial markets in particular.
72 Franks and Sussman (1999).
Volym D:118 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
9 Policy Implications
The fundamental conclusion of our analysis of the causes of financial
First, unlike the logical conclusion from recent studies relating financial development to legal origin, our analysis offers hope to those countries that have not had the good fortune to be colonized by the British. Instead of abandoning a legal tradition (not an easy task even if it did not destroy the specific capital of lawyers), they only have to deal with the politics. Clearly, reforming the political system is not much easier than reforming the legal system. However, it may be relatively easy empowering constituencies in favor of financial development.
This is extremely important for transition economies. It is not sufficient to design the rules appropriately, it is also necessary to strengthen the political support for the market in the longer term. The importance of this point can be appreciated by looking at the different long term effects of privatizations in Russia and Poland. Both plans were well thought out. If anything, the Russian plan could pride itself on using top U.S. legal scholars to design its corporation law. The Russian reform could be considered the ultimate social experiment in which the ”right” set of laws are introduced to promote financial development. But the Polish reforms have proved more resilient.
The Polish plan placed the shares of state enterprises in big mutual funds, that could not directly run companies, but could gather large enough blocks to control them. Individual investors were then given shares in the mutual funds. This created a powerful group in favor of market development: mutual fund managers. This group successfully fought for more disclosure and more transparency. It was crucial that the role of outside monitors was given to mutual fund managers, as opposed to bank managers. Bankers have a vested interest in maintaining the market opaque in order to exploit the return to their investment in information.
Undoubtedly, Russia was more difficult terrain to start with. But the problems were potentially compounded by the political constituencies empowered by the reforms. The shares of state enterprises were given directly to the citizens, while the control was handed over to corporate
SOU 2000:11 Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:119
managers. These managers (former communist appartchiks who are still very influential) found themselves in the position of the rich in our parable. They controlled monopolist firms and had all the interest in opposing any move toward a more transparent and efficient market, which would have implied less independence for them and more opportunity for entry for competitors. Not surprisingly, few would associate the terms transparent and good governance with Russian firms, and the financial sector is moribund.
A second implication is that outside forces are extremely important in supporting markets. Outside forces such as financial and industrial investors tend to be more immune to cooptation or threats from the government. They do not benefit from many of the politically motivated internal transfers and subsidies. Not being part of the cozy domestic compact, they rely on transparency and legal enforcement. As a result, their interests coincide with those of markets, and they are more sensitive to attempts to shut it down, imposing some discipline on unbridled central power. In the 1930s and 1940s the
In this respect, the role played by international organizations is ambivalent. On the one hand, they had, and still have, a tremendous effect in promoting the cause of liberalization in many countries. The European Union, for instance, is more promarket than any of its individual member (with the possible exception of the United Kingdom). The World Trade Organization helps prevent tariff wars, which proved to be so devastating in the 1930s. On the other hand, the centralization of political power in these organizations runs the risk of weakening the salutary role of outside forces. In a hypothetical new world order, ruled by a supernational Government, outside forces would disappear. There would be no foreign countries to emigrate to, no foreign market to access for capital, no foreign competitors to enter the market. A supernational Government will find it easy to intervene,
And the threat of an
Volym D:120 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
is very salutary from an economic point of view. It is an essential part of the working of a market economy, which accentuates the need for action, accelerating the recovery. But it is extremely costly from a political point of view, especially because pain is not a political message that sells well. All too often, before the market revives itself, the Government intervenes to diffuse the cost of the crisis, slowing the road to recovery.
The fear of a political backlash should caution us against taking for granted that financial development is unidirectional, and that the generalized consensus in favor of markets is irreversible because of their obvious efficiency. Our historical account shows that in time of crises a political backlash may occur and it can have very
The need for some safety net is even more important today, given the potential sources of political tensions looming in front of us. One is represented by the distributional consequences of technological change. While extremely beneficial, technological change has enormous distributional effects, which are amplified by markets. For example, in the United States the wage differential for college graduates has been increasing for the last thirty years. So has the return to talent. These differences are likely to increase redistributional conflict in the future.
The other potential source of political tension is the progressive aging of the population (at least in the most developed economies), with the consequent need to pay for unfunded pension plans. This need will increase the demand for redistribution and, thus, the demand for a more centralized economy. As we already mentioned, in a command and control economy the costs of redistribution are lower, both from an economic and a political point of view, because cross subsidies become
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:121 |
|
|
less visible and easier to implement. Thus, the aging of the population could enhance the pressure for more intervention.
In the face of these threats, the survival of financial markets, and in general of market economies, crucially depends upon the ability to preempt these sources of political tensions.
Volym D:122 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
10 Conclusions
The quest for the ultimate cause of financial backwardness is not another senseless academic exercise, but a first order question, which carries enormous policy consequences. The answer should shape any attempt to reform a financial system.
Our conclusion that politics is the main villain carries both a hope and a warning. The hope is that the benefits of financial development are within every country’s reach. And today many forces are joining to ease the path to financial development. Increased international competition is eliminating the monopolistic rents of local producers not only weakening their opposition to financial development, but also transforming them into advocates for a better financial system. The large number of countries that in the last few years have introduced new laws in favor of investors supports this hope.
The warning is that the dramatic progress that financial markets have made in the last decade is not irreversible. This has been a time of expansion. The market as an institution remains politically fragile and the inevitable contraction will highlight new political challenges. Only if promarket forces actively recognize these will researchers at the end of the 21st century not have to wonder what caused financial markets to retreat over the turn of the 20th century.
SOU 2000:11 |
Politics, Law and Financial Development Volym D:123 |
|
|
References
Bencivenga and Smith Bencivenga, (1991), Valerie and Smith Bruce. ”Financial Intermediation and Endogenous growth”, Review of Economic Studies, April, 58,
Boone, P., A. Breach, E. Friedman and S. Johnson, (1998), ”Corporate Governance and the Asian Financial Crisis,
Brealey, R. and S. Myers, (1996), Principles of Corporate Finance, McGraw Hill, 5th edition.
Clark, R.C., (1986), Corporate Law, Corporate law, Boston: Little, Brown, c1986.
David, René and John E.C. Brierley, (1978), Major Legal Systems in the World Today: An Introduction to the Comparative Study of Law, London Stevens; New York: distributed in U.S.A. by Free Press of Glencoe.
Easterbrook, F. and D. Fischel, (1991), The Economic Analysis of Corporate Law, Harvard University Press.
Engelbourg, Saul and Leonard Bushkoff, (1996), The Man Who Found the Money: John Stewart Kennedy and the Financing of the Western Railroads, East Lansing: Michigan State University Press.
Kroszner, R., (2000), ”Is The Financial System Politically Independent? Perspectives on the Political Economy of Banking and Financial Regulation”, Supplement No. 25 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
La Porta, Florencio, Lopez de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, (1997), ”The Legal Determinants of External Finance”, Journal of Finance, 52.
La Porta, R.,
Myers, S., (1977), The determinants of corporate borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics, 5,
Powell, Ellis, (1915), The Evolution of the Money Market
Prescott, E., (1986), ”Theory Ahead of Measurement”, Minneapolis Fed Quarterly Review.
Rajan, R., (1998), ”The Past and Future of Commercial Banking Viewed through an Incomplete Contract Lens”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 30, (3),
Volym D:124 Supplement 24 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, (1995), ”What Do We Know about Capital Structure? Some Evidence From International Data”, Journal of Finance (1995), 50,
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, (1998a), ”Financial Dependence and Growth”, The American Economic Review, (1998), 88,
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, (1998b), ”The Tyranny of the Inefficient: An Inquiry into the Adverse Consequences of Power Struggles”, forthcoming in the Journal of Public Economics.
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, (1998c), ”Which Capitalism? Lessons From the East Asia Crisis”, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance.
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, (1999), ”The Firm as a Dedicated Hierarchy: A Theory of the Origins and Growth of Firms”, http://gsblgz.uchicago.edu.
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, (2000), ”Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth”, Supplement No. 23 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Roe, M., (1994), Strong Managers and Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American Corporate Finance, Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J.
Seligman J., (1995), The Transformation of Wall Street, Northeastern University Press, Boston 1995, p.42.
Shleifer and R. Vishny. (1997), ”A Survey of Corporate Governance'',
Journal of Finance.
Tunc, Andre, (1991), Corporate Law in R. Bauxbaum, G. Hertig, A. Hirsch, and K. Hopt, eds.: European Business Law: Legal and Economic Analysis of Integration and Hamornization, de Gruyter, Berlin.
Zingales, L., (1995), ”What Determines the Value of Corporate Votes?”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics 110:
SOU 2000:11 |
Volym D:127 |
|
|
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?
Perspectives on The Political Economy of Banking and Financial Regulation
by
Randall S. Kroszner*
Supplement number 25 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Views, suggestions, and opinions expressed in this study represent the personal views of the author and not necessarily those of the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
September, 1999
* Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, Graduate School of Business, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, USA.
Volym D:128 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Table of Contents
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish) ..................................................... |
129 |
|
Summary............................................................................................. |
131 |
|
1 |
Introduction ............................................................................... |
133 |
2 |
Alternative Approaches to the Political Economy of |
|
|
Regulation .................................................................................. |
135 |
2.1 |
Public Interest........................................................................ |
135 |
2.2 |
Private Interest ...................................................................... |
136 |
2.3 |
Ideology ................................................................................ |
140 |
2.4 |
Institutions............................................................................. |
140 |
2.5 |
Leviathan .............................................................................. |
142 |
3
Regulatory Reform .................................................................... |
143 |
4Public Finance Motives behind Financial Reform and Globalization: The Case of Government Securities
|
Markets Reform......................................................................... |
146 |
5 |
What is the Role of Crises in the |
|
|
Reform? .................................................................................... |
150 |
6 |
Conclusions for Facilitating the Policy Reform Process ............ |
153 |
References........................................................................................... |
156 |
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:129 |
|
|
|
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish)
Syftet med studier i politisk ekonomi är att analysera hur regleringar tillkommer, vilka krafter som påverkar denna process och vilka krafter som verkar för att konservera respektive förändra existerande regle- ringar. Denna bilaga illustrerar a) att det finansiella systemet inte är oberoende av det politiska systemet, och b) vad detta ömsesidiga bero- ende betyder för regleringar och regleringsprocessen på det finansiella området. Detta innebär ett annat och kompletterande synsätt på regle- ringar i förhållande till en mer normativ analys av ”optimal” reglering.
I bilagan diskuteras fem olika motiv till finansiella regleringar och avregleringar. För det första finns det ett kollektivt motiv till regleringar där syftet är att maximera den samhällsekonomiska välfärden. Eftersom många regleringar inte kan förklaras på detta sätt behandlas för det andra olika privata intressen som drivkrafter i regleringsprocessen. Även om teorin om lobbying från privata intressegrupper kan förklara många former av regleringar har den svårt att förklara trenden mot avregleringar under det senaste decenniet. Ideologiska skift bland lag- stiftare och väljare blir en tredje förklaring, även om orsakerna till dessa skift är svårfångade. För det fjärde kan den institutionella besluts- strukturen påverka både olika intressegruppers incitament att organisera sig och deras möjligheter att påverka besluten. Slutligen kan politikernas och byråkraternas budgetmässiga överväganden motivera regleringar som genererar offentliga inkomster.
Dessa perspektiv underlättar en förståelse för hur teknologiska, juridiska och ekonomiska innovationer har drivit fram de globala finan- siella avregleringarna. De finansiella kriserna har också betytt mycket för att driva fram reformer och förändringar av regleringar.
Bilagan avslutas med fem slutsatser om hur den politiska reform- arbetet kan underlättas. För det första kan väl genomförda konsekvens- analyser av olika förslag spela en viktig roll för att upplysa allmänheten och beslutsfattare. För det andra kan konkurrens mellan olika rivalise- rande intressegrupper minska risken att få regleringar som gynnar vissa grupper på det allmännas bekostnad. För det tredje, kan en reformering av regleringar underlättas om den offentliga beslutsprocessen stimulerar konkurrens mellan olika intressegrupper. För det fjärde skulle en större genomlysning av det statliga deltagandet och tillsynen möjliggöra en bättre utvärdering av statens roll i det finansiella systemet. För det femte kan ett inflöde av utländska aktörer vara en positiv kraft, eftersom dessa
Volym D:130 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
har färre politiska kontakter och mindre möjligheter att skaffa sig fördelar i regleringssystemet.
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:131 |
|
|
|
Summary
Rather than take regulations as given, the political economy approach attempts to provide a positive analysis of how and why regulations evolve as they do and what forces can lead to their durability as well as their potential for change. The focus of this paper will be to illustrate how the banking and financial system is not independent of politics and what implications this interdependence has for understanding regulations and reform. This perspective provides an alternative lens through which to analyze regulation and which is complementary to the traditional normative analysis undertaken by economists studying ”optimal” regulation.
Five complementary positive political economy approaches are outlined and applied to understand the pattern of banking and financial regulation and deregulation. First, the public interest approach emphasizes the maximization of social welfare as the motivation for regulation. Since many regulations cannot be rationalized on such grounds, a second approach emphasizing private interests is then developed. This theory focuses on the strength and organization of special interests groups that compete to lobby for protections and privileges. While the private interest theory is able to explain many forms of regulation, it has only partial success in explaining the recent trend towards deregulation. Changing ideology of legislators and voters provides a third alternative. Pro- and anti- business ideological commitments may play a role, but it is difficult to understand exactly what drives ideological change. Fourth, the institutional structure of
These approaches then help to identify technological, legal, and economic innovations that have been driving the global move toward financial liberalization and regulatory reform. Changes in the government securities markets
Volym D:132 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
The paper concludes with five lessons from the positive political economy approaches for ways to facilitate the policy reform process. First, careful
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:133 |
|
|
|
1 Introduction**
The structure and regulation of a country’s financial markets and institutions are the focus of much policy attention for a number of economic and political reasons. Banks and other financial institutions encourage and collect savings that finance a country’s economic growth. By allocating the savings to enterprises and monitoring the use of the funds, these institutions and markets play an integral part of the corporate governance system that ultimately affects the productivity of resources throughout the economy (see Rajan and Zingales 2000a and 2000b). Banks and other financial institutions also play a key role in transmitting the government’s monetary and credit policies to the rest of the economy. Parts of the financial sector are effectively regulated as means to provide subsidized credit or services to targeted groups (including the government itself) and to protect particular groups (from, for example, competition, hostile takeovers, or expropriation).
While the economics of financial regulation have been studied extensively (see, e.g., Herring and Santomero 2000 and Kroszner 1998a), the politics have received less – albeit increasing – attention.
Rather than take regulations as given, the political economy approach attempts to provide a positive analysis of how and why regulations evolve as they do and what forces can lead to their durability as well as their potential for change. The focus of this study will be to illustrate how the banking and financial system is not independent of politics and what implications this interdependence has for understanding regulations and reform. This perspective provides an alternative lens through which to analyze regulation and which is complementary to the traditional normative analysis undertaken by economists studying ”optimal” regulation.
When the infamous American bank robber Willie Sutton was asked why he robbed banks, he replied ”That’s where the money is”. The same might be said for why there is such involvement of the government with the banking and financial system – that’s where the money is. This idea
** An earlier version of this study was presented at Symposium on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Industry, organized by the Bank of Sweden Tercentenary Foundation, Stockholm, Sweden, March
Volym D:134 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
manifests itself in a number of ways, related to the positive political economy analysis. In the next section, I briefly outline a number of approaches to understanding the political economy of government involvement in the economy and then try to understand why the banking and financial system appears to be particularly vulnerable to politicization.
I then examine the technological, legal, and economic shocks that the political economy approach would suggest are the primary factors that disturb a regulatory equilibrium in banking and financial markets. A case analysis of the
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:135 |
|
|
|
2Alternative Approaches to the Political Economy of Regulation
Both
2.1Public Interest
The traditional approach that economists took to explaining the existence of regulation emphasized that regulations exist to correct market failures and protect poorly informed consumers from harm.1 From this perspective, regulatory intervention occurs primarily to maximize social welfare, so this approach is often called the ”public interest theory” of regulation. Public interest rationales are given for capital regulation and deposit insurance to provide a sound banking system because stability of the financial system can have spillover effects for general macroeconomic performance (e.g., Kaufman and Kroszner 1997). Statutory protections of shareholders and creditors from ex post appropriation and supervisory agencies in like a Securities and Exchange Commission are rationalized on the grounds of investor and consumer protection.
A key challenge to the public interest view is that many forms of regulation have little or no redeeming social value. Entry restrictions that protect banks or other financial institutions from competition, portfolio restrictions that hinder diversification, and geographic restrictions that have prevented expansion within a country or across national borders are
1 Joskow and Noll (1981) call this normative analysis as positive theory.
Volym D:136 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
generally difficult to rationalize on public interest grounds. Statutes or regulatory procedures that protect incumbent management from many forms of discipline by shareholders or outsiders provide additional examples. Regulation that does not appear to serve a public interest also is ubiquitous in other sectors (see Stigler, 1988).
Virtually all regulation, regardless of whether it may have a public interest rationale, has significant distributional consequences. The parties affected by the regulation thus have an incentive to try to ensure that the government structures the regulation in such a way as to benefit them. A public interest argument often is used to mask the private interests that the intervention serves. Private interests may try to confuse the public debate by providing false or misleading information to make it difficult to discern what policy would improve social welfare (e.g., Kane 1996 and Dewatripont and Tirole 1999).
2.2Private Interest
The ”private interest theory” of regulation, also called the economic theory of regulation, characterizes the regulatory process as one of interest group competition in which compact,
The incentives for such regulatory behavior may be direct or indirect. Pressure may be exerted directly on politicians, though campaign contributions or votes. The politicians then pass a new statute or pressure the regulators to act sympathetically towards the interest group. Indirect incentives may come through regulators understanding that cooperative behavior may be rewarded with lucrative employment opportunities in the industry after leaving the government, a practice so common in the past with Japanese Ministry of Finance officials that it is euphemistically called amakudari or the ”descent from heaven”.
The effectiveness of the interest groups depends upon a number of factors. First, cohesive groups will find it easier to organize and overcome
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:137 |
|
|
|
benefit them. Producers of goods and services tend to be more compact and better organized than consumers, so there is a tendency for regulation on net to benefit producers more than consumers (Stigler 1971). The parallel in corporate finance is that incumbent managements tend to be better organized and more effective than dispersed shareholders, so there is a tendency for regulation to benefit incumbent management against small shareholders (see Hellwig 1998 and below). The ability of a group to organize is often inversely related to its size, but many labor unions and trade organizations have been able to develop effective lobbying bodies through carefully crafted incentives that provide a variety of information and support services in return for membership (see Olson 1965).
Second, groups tend to be more effective not only when the benefits are concentrated among group members but also when the costs of the regulation are relatively diffuse. A compact group of potential losers each of whom would experience high losses associated with the regulation will be likely to form a lobby that will try to counteract the original interest group’s pressure. Interest groups most directly affected by the regulation may build a coalition to lobby for or against the regulation.2
Third, in addition to the diffusion of the costs across different groups, the level of the costs relative to the benefits obtained by the interest group play an important role (Becker 1983). Deadweight loss is defined as precisely the difference between the winner’s benefit minus the loser’s cost from the change in output generated by the regulation. Factors affecting the ”efficiency” of the regulatory or transfer mechanism thus may have an important impact on political outcomes. As the deadweight loss of grows, for example, the losers are losing more for each krona of the winner’s gain. When this gap widens, losers have a greater incentive to fight each krona of the winner’s gain and the winners have less incentive to fight for each krona of the loser’s loss. In other words, when deadweight losses are high, an interest group faces greater opposition to
2 In addition, groups with completely unconnected interests may form ”support trading” or ”log rolling” coalitions. Two groups may agree to support each other even if the members of one group are not affected by the regulations that the other wants. Tariffs are a classic case of ”log rolling” in which, say, lumber and glass producers support each other’s call for higher protection, thereby providing greater support for higher tariffs than otherwise would be (Irwin and Kroszner 1999).
Volym D:138 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
its protective regulation on the margin and hence is less likely to be successful.3
Similarly, politicians in electoral democracies are concerned about finding an optimal support coalition to promote their
The private interest theory thus helps to explain why the banking and financial system is particularly susceptible to political influence. The banking system provides an effective but
3Becker (1983) argues that competition among lobbying groups thus will lead to the most efficient (lowest deadweight cost) regulations being chosen, so there is a tendency for regulation to be ”efficient” in this sense. Wittman (1995) takes this argument further to conclude that both democratic institutions and outcomes are efficient.
4When the constraint of future elections is less binding on politicians, they may engage in less
5Also, flat rate deposit insurance tends to subsidize the smaller and riskier banks at the expense of the larger, better diversified, and safer banks. Lobbying for flat rate deposit insurance historically has been consistent with this pattern of relative benefits (e.g., Calomiris and White 1994 and Hubbard et al. 1996).
6Gershenkron (1962), for example, argued that the German government fostered the development of strong universal banks in Germany, at the expense of financial market development, to promote rapid economic development in the nineteenth century.
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:139 |
|
|
|
Since the government is so heavily involved in banking, it may be very difficult to have effective government regulation of the domestic banking and financial sector. In these circumstances, simply hiring more and
In developing a political economy explanation of practices and regulations in corporate finance, Hellwig (1998) emphasizes the contrasting interests and organizational costs facing insiders versus outsiders. He explains, for example, the heavy reliance in firms on internally generated cash flows, rather than external sources of funds, to finance investment as arising not from failures in the capital markets but from the incentives of managers to avoid subjecting themselves to outside discipline. From this perspective, investment choices could be distorted by managers taking into account the potential loss of their private benefits associated with using outside sources of finance.
Insiders, such as firm management and controlling shareholders, have incentives to try to insulate themselves from external pressures and to attempt to disenfranchise other shareholders (Hellwig 1998). Incumbent management and controlling shareholders of large and
Volym D:140 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
2.3Ideology
While the private interest theory has had much success in explaining a wide variety of regulatory interventions that are difficult to rationalize on public interest grounds, it has been less effective in explaining the widespread economic deregulation that has taken place in many countries during the last two decades (Peltzman 1989 and Noll 1989 but see Kroszner and Strahan 1999). Many political scientists and some economists emphasize the importance of beliefs and ”ideology” of voters and politicians to explain regulation and deregulation (e.g., Kalt and Zupan 1984, Goldstein 1988, and Poole and Rosenthal 1997). Difference across countries or among citizens over time in their general beliefs about the appropriate role of the government in economic affairs might affect the extent of intervention. Roe (1994), for example, has argued that populist fears of excessive concentration of power in the hands of financial elites was an important driving force behind many banking and financial regulations in the early part of this century (but see Hellwig 1998 for an alternative interpretation).
Poole and Rosenthal (1997) have developed a useful measure of ideology based on
Identifying the driving forces behind changes in ideology over time, however, have been difficult. What constitutes ”ideology” and whether it can be measured independent of economic interests is the subject of an extensive and ongoing controversy (see Peltzman 1984 and overviews by Bender and Lott 1996 and Poole and Rosenthal 1996).
2.4Institutions
The new institutional economics approach emphasizes transactions costs and institutional arrangements for
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:141 |
|
|
|
approach examines how alternative
The regulation of bank powers illustrates the endogeneity of interests with respect to the regulatory framework (e.g., Kroszner 1996). In 1933, the U.S. adopted the
The silver lining in the cloud of
Volym D:142 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
2.5Leviathan
Politicians and the bureaucracy may be considered a distinct interest group concerned about expanding their size and influence over the economy. Niskanen (1971) and Brennan and Buchanan (1977) suggest that an objective of the government may be to maximize or, on the margin, increase its size and expenditures and discuss institutional structures that can mitigate the tendency toward growth. This view has been characterized as the ”Leviathan” approach.
The fiscal demands of the government help to explain some of the close relation between politics and the banking and financial sector and the origins of numerous regulations. Geographic restrictions on banks in the U.S., for example, arose in the early nineteenth century as a way for state governments to maximize revenues from the sale of bank charters by providing a series of local monopolies (Kroszner 1997). The federal government began to grant bank charters during the U.S. Civil War to create a new class of banks that would hold federal debt and, thereby, facilitate the financing of the war effort. The Bank of England was founded as a way to aid in the financing of the Crown in England. More recently, as governments have come to rely more heavily on deficit financing through the issue of sovereign debt, reforms of the government securities markets around the world can be understood from this perspective (as will be discussed below).7 Debt moratoria, debt abrogation, and changes bankruptcy law also can be seen in this light (e.g., Berglof and Rosenthal 1999, Bolton and Rosenthal 1999, and Kroszner 1999).
7 The government also raises revenues thorough seniorage, and the ability to tax through inflation is another reason for the government’s long involvement with money and banking affairs.
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:143 |
|
|
|
3
The
Technological change is often cited as a key force behind the innovations in financial markets and institutions during the last two decades. In the
From the
Volym D:144 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
branch, thereby permitted the growth of interstate ATM networks. ATM networks then rapidly spread worldwide.
Second,
Since the increasing elasticity of deposits supplied to banks reduces the value of geographical restrictions to their traditional beneficiaries, these beneficiaries had less incentive to fight strenuously to maintain them. Also, as elasticities increase, there are fewer rents to share among competing groups so regulation becomes less likely (Peltzman 1989). While any deregulation that eliminates inefficient regulation is broadly consistent with the public interest theory, the timing of the deregulation is difficult to explain by that approach. The opening of banking markets occurs precisely when the geographic restrictions are becoming less burdensome for the public, due to the
On the lending side, increasing sophistication of
Technological change thus has diminished the value of specialized local knowledge that
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:145 |
|
|
|
borrowers from the local banks also would be more likely to favor the entry of large and foreign banks into local markets (Kroszner and Strahan 1999).
The method of opening up of the banking markets also is consistent with the private interest theory (see Kroszner 1997). Typically, new foreign entry is first permitted through investment in existing banks and mergers, rather than de novo entry (particularly of institutions that are in financial distress, as Citicorp’s new entry into Mexico illustrates). By removing the geographic barriers in this way, the small, local banks have an opportunity to share in the benefits of deregulation by selling out at a premium rather than being competed out of existence. The smaller banks in the country thus would tend to lobby for foreign entry through mergers because they would prefer to have more potential bidders in the market, which tends to increase the premium paid for small banks (Brickley and James 1987).
An increase in foreign financial institution penetration can generate a virtuous circle in that foreign banks tend to be less politically connected and less likely to be able to ”capture” the regulatory authorities. In addition, they are less likely to succumb to pressure for directed lending by the government. With capture less likely and fewer direct benefits to the politicians of bank regulation (e.g., through quid pro quos for directed lending), regulatory reform becomes more likely. New Zealand, for example, began its reform process when roughly 30 percent of the banking system was already foreign owned. By the end of the reform process, a very large fraction of the banks had become foreign owned. This helps to increase the likelihood that the reforms are sustainable and not simply temporary. In sum, technological change was a shock to the old
Volym D:146 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
4Public Finance Motives behind Financial Reform and Globalization: The Case of Government Securities Markets Reform
Since the late 1970s, there has been dramatic growth in the use of
Motivated by a desire to keep financing costs on their rapidly mounting debt relatively low, politicians thus had incentives to broaden their sources of funding. Consistent with our deadweight cost analysis above, politicians would like to engage in their redistributive activities but must take into account the losses associated with the transfers. The worldwide reforms of the structure and operation of government securities markets during the last two decades, particularly in emerging markets, can be explained in terms of this motive. Auctions replaced or significantly supplemented the traditional placement of securities with
8This form of financing could be seen as a mild form of financial repression (Fry 1997).
9There is a long and rich history linking a government's financing desires and financial regulation. During the first fiscal revolution in the U.S. when state governments began to rely heavily on debt financing in the 1840s, for example, many states adopted ”free banking” statutes. This legal change eased entry into banking but required the banks to hold state government securities as reserves, thereby boosting the demand for the state's bonds (see Kroszner 1997a and Kroszner and Strahan 1999).
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:147 |
|
|
|
the banks. Simultaneously, the government created or formalized a primary dealer system in which it authorizes specially designated dealers to have the exclusive right to bid directly in the auctions and to have the responsibility of distributing the securities to investors.
An important feature of these reforms was that
The internationalization of the government debt markets also has been associated with an increase in the liquidity of these markets. The primary dealers have an obligation to the government, as well as their own private incentive, to foster the growth of a liquid secondary market in government bonds. Liquid secondary markets help to reduce the government's financing costs, by fostering demand by investors (especially foreign investors) who are more willing to hold instruments which have easily observable market prices and can be easily traded. Liquidity also facilitates the dealers' distribution of the securities to investors. The depth of the government securities markets typically has been associated with an increase in the depth and development of other securities in these countries and increased foreign involvement.
As the economic theory of regulatory reform would suggest, the changes which began the opening of domestic financial markets to foreign competition and created liquid debt markets, providing another form of competition to the banking sector, did not occur without some quid pro quo for the banking industry. In particular, the choice of auction technique illustrates a role for private interests in the details of the institutional changes.
Governments consistently adopted
10See Drazen (1997) for a detailed
11In
Volym D:148 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
in the recent reforms contrasts sharply with the sustained academic criticism that this format has received relative to the
In addition, potential bidders without access to detailed information on which to base the estimates of the secondary market value would be less willing to participate directly in a
In principle, the revenue loss from the downward shift in demand at a
The
auction, all of the successful bidders pay the same price. Who wins is determined the same way as in the
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:149 |
|
|
|
revenue rose, suggesting that the
Given that the potential problems of the
An alternative explanation is that the
12 Rapid technological innovation, however, has begun to erode the information advantages associated with being a primary dealer. Proliferation of
Volym D:150 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
5What is the Role of Crises in the
Reforms are often associated with banking and economic crises, and the ”crisis” hypothesis provides an alternative to the
Are crises an independent factor which can be said to ”cause” reform to occur? Rodrik (1996) has been critical of the crisis hypothesis because it is almost nonfalsifiable – if reform does not occur, proponents of this view will say that the crisis was not sufficiently severe – and because reforms responding to similar crises take very different forms (e.g., Caprio and Klingebiel 1996). The U.S., for example, responded to the banking and economic crisis of the early 1930s by fragmenting the financial system (Kroszner 1996). The
From a
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:151 |
|
|
|
tended to support federal deposit insurance, for example, they became politically powerful enough to enact it only in 1933 (Hubbard et al. 1996, but also see Calomiris and White 1994).
Second, economic upheaval can change the relative costs and benefits of particular regulations. An interest rate ceiling, which may act like a
Third, crisis can also affect bureaucratic incentives for regulatory change. Deposit insurance, for example, commits the government to bail- out banks that have liquidity and solvency problems. During times of crisis, deposit insurance funds typically are bankrupt so an explicit
Finally, the enormous costs of a financial crisis may serve an important educational role for the public (see Kane 1996). During normal times, individual voters may not know the full value of the implicit or explicit guarantees that the government, that is, the taxpayer, is making. After a crisis, however, the government is likely to have to raise taxes and sell bonds in order to pay for the
The reform and repeal of the Argentine deposit insurance system follows this pattern. During the 1980s, Argentina experienced two major
Volym D:152 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
banking crises. The first in
This reform, however, was not completely sustained. Five years later, during the Tequila crisis, the interests in favor of deposit insurance grew and a private deposit insurance scheme was instituted (Guidotti 1996). The deposit insurance premia are relatively high but the insurance agency is owned by the banks that contribute to it. Thus, if the system stays healthy, they earn the profits from the insurance agency but will bear the burdens when the banks require
The changes in geographic restrictions within the U.S. also can be understood within this framework. Kane (1996) argues that an important shock to the old equilibrium favoring branching restrictions was an increase in the public’s understanding of the costliness of having
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:153 |
|
|
|
6Conclusions for Facilitating the Policy Reform Process
The thrust of the arguments above focus on interest group competition and how the battle among the interests will be a key determinant of the regulatory outcomes. Are careful scholarly analyses of regulations and their reforms then of little relevance for policy so academics should retreat to the Ivory Tower? An organized interest group, money, and/or votes may be necessary for a view to prevail in the political marketplace but it is not sufficient, due to the rivalry among interest groups. Theory and facts, not only money and power, are relevant to the debates. Without an interest group to champion a position, however, an argument may have little effect. (Television, radio, and the internet, however, have been reducing the costs for both information to be disseminated and for groups to organize.)
A logical and empirically supported argument affects the productivity of the lobbying efforts by an interest group, much like a technological shock that can increase the productivity of investments. Although rival interests will always have an incentive to provide disinformation and generate ”hack” alternative studies, a well executed can be a great help to a particular group. In terms of Becker’s pressure group model, careful studies can inform the rival groups about the size of the dead weight losses involved with policy alternatives. Reducing uncertainty about the outcome can energize the losing side to increase lobbying effort. Thus, one implication of the
13 Kane (1996) argues that bank regulators and beneficiaries of restrictions on geographic expansion of banks purposefully misinformed the public and legislators about the costs of the regulations. Only a combination of large failures and costly
Volym D:154 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
A second implication is that competition among rival interest groups can increase the likelihood of beneficial reform. Rival groups have an incentive to battle each other in addition to battling the consumer. If they dissipate their efforts against each other, they are less likely to be able to support narrow special interest regulation. In many emerging markets today, e.g., Russia, a major question concerns whether creating universal banks would allow one particular interest to have too much political power and thwart reform. In addition, the rival groups have an incentive to try to unmask any misinformation that the competing side is generating. This can help to inform both the
Third, the structure of regulatory and government institutions also plays a role. A clear structure of legislative oversight of the regulatory process through, for example, specific committees in the Parliament with responsibility for banking and financial matters may provide a forum which fosters the information generation process (Gilligan and Krehbiel 1989, McCubbins, Noll, and Weingast 1989, Krehbiel 1991, Austin- Smith and Wright 1992 and 1994, Kroszner and Stratmann 1998). Similarly, the incentives for groups to overcome
Fourth, greater transparency in government involvement in the financial system is significant. Politicians often use the financial system, either through implicit guidance or explicit through state owned banks, to provide
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:155 |
|
|
|
of financial institutions also would permit increased monitoring of the government’s role in the financial system.
Finally, foreign entry can generate a virtuous circle because foreign institutions tend to be less politically connected domestically and less likely to be able to capture the regulatory authorities. Foreign institutions also are less likely to succumb to pressure for directed lending by the government. With capture less likely and fewer direct benefits to the politicians of regulation (e.g., through quid pro quos for directed lending), regulatory reform becomes more likely. While there is no simple formula for successful and sustained banking and financial regulatory reform, a positive analysis of the
Volym D:156 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
References
Alesina, Alberto and Allan Drazen, (1991), ”Why Are Stab ilizations Delayed?” American Economic Review, December:
Alston, Lee, Thrainn Eggertsson, and Douglass North, (1996), eds.
Empirical Studies in Institutional Change, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bartolini, Leonardo and Carlo Cottarelli, (1997), ”Treasury Bill Auctions: Issues and Uses”, pp.
Becker, Gary S., (1983), ”A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence”, Quarterly Journal of Economics:
Bender, Bruce, and John R. Lott, (1996), ”Legislator Voting and Shirking: A Critical Review of the Literature”, Public Choice 87:
Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman, (1996), ”The Appropriate Role of Bank Regulation”, The Economic Journal 106, May:
Berglöf, Erik and Howard Rosenthal, (1999), ”The Political Ec onomy of American Bankruptcy: The Evidence from Roll Call Voting, 1800- 1978”, working paper, Princeton University, April.
Bolton, Patrick and Howard Rosenthal, (1999), ”Political Intervention in Debt Contracts: Moratoria and Bailouts”, working paper, Princeton University, March.
Brennan, Geoffrey and James Buchanan, (1977), ”Towards a Tax Constitution for Leviathan”, Journal of Public Economics 8:
Brickley, James A. and Christopher M. James, (1987), ”The Takeover Market, Corporate Board Composition, and Ownership Structure: The Case of Banking”, Journal of Law and Economics 30, April:
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:157 |
|
|
|
Calomiris, Charles and Eugene White, (1994), ”The Origins of Federal Deposit Insurance”, pp.
Caprio, Gerard, Jr. and Daniela Klingebiel, (1996), ”Dealing with Bank Insolvencies: Cross Country Experience”, Policy Research Department Working Paper, The World Bank, February.
Casella, Alesandra and Barry Eichengreen, (1994), ”Can Foreign Aid Accelerate Stabilization?”, Working Paper.
Dewatripont, Mathias and Jean Tirole, (1999), ”A dvocates”, Journal of Political Economy 107, February:
Dixit, Avinash, (1996), The Making of Economic Policy: A
Drazen, Allan, (1997), ”Towards a
Fernandez, Raquel and Dani Rodrik, (1991), ”Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of
Fischel, Daniel, (1997), Payback, New York.
Friedman, Milton, (1960), A Program for Monetary Stability, New York: Fordham University Press.
Fry, Maxwell, (1997), Emancipating the Banking System and Developing Markets for Government Debt, London: Routledge.
Gerschenkron, A., (1962), Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Gilligan, Thomas and Keith Krehbiel, (1989), ”Asymmetric Information and Legislative Rules with a Heterogeneous Committee”, American Journal of Political Science 33:
Goldstein, Judith, (1988), ”Ideas, Institutions, and American Trade Policy”, International Organization 42:
Guidotti, Pablo, (1996), ”Debt, Monetary, and Banking Policy in Emerging Markets: Reflections from the ‘Tequila’ Effect,” University of Maryland, Department of Economics Working Paper No. 28, December.
Hellwig, Martin, (1998), ”On the Ec onomics and Politics of Corporate Finance and Corporate Control,” working paper.
Herring, Richard and Anthony Santomero, (2000), ”What Is Optimal Financial Regulation?”, Supplement No. 26 to the Government Inquiry on the Internationel Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Volym D:158 Supplement 25 SOU 2000:11
Holderness, Clifford, Randall Kroszner, and Dennis Sheehan, (1999), ”Were the Good Old Days that Good? Changes in Managerial Stock Ownership since the Great Depression”, Journal of Finance, April:
Hubbard, R. Glenn, Darius Palia, and Nicolas Economides, (1996), ”The Political Economy of Branching Restrictions and Deposit Insurance”, Journal of Law and Economics, October.
Irwin, Douglas and Randall Kroszner, (1999), ”Interests, Institutions, and Ideology in Securing Policy Change: The Republican Conversion to Trade Liberalization after
Jayaratne, Jith and Philip E. Strahan, (1996), ”The
Jensen, Michael, (1991), ”Corporate Control and the Politics of Finance”, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 4:
Joskow, Paul and Roger Noll, (1981), ”Regulation in Theory and Practice: An Overview”, pp.
Kane, Edward, (1984), ”Regulatory Structure in Futures Markets: Jurisdictional Competition between the SEC, the CFTC, and Other Agencies”, Journal of Futures Markets 4:
Kane, Edward, (1987), ”Competitive Financial Reregulation: An International Perspective”, pp.
Kane, Edward J., (1988), ”How Market Forces Influence the Structure of Financial Regulation,” chapter 9 in Kushmeider, ed.,
Restructuring Banking and Financial Services, Washington: American Enterprise Institute.
Kane, Edward J., (1996), ”De Jure Interstate Banking: Why Only Now?”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 28; 2, May:
Kaufman, George and Randall Kroszner, (1997), ”How Should Financial Institutions and Markets be Structured?”, pp.
Klein, Daniel, (1999), ed. What Do Economists Contribute?, New York: New York University Press.
Krehbiel, Keith, (1991), Information and Legislative Organization, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
SOU 2000:11 |
Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… |
Volym D:159 |
|
|
|
Kroszner, Randall S., (1996a), ”The Evolution of Universal Banking and Its Regulation in Twentieth Century America,” pp.
Kroszner, Randall S., (1996b), ”An Analysis of Bank Privatization”, working paper, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago.
Kroszner, Randall S., (1997a), ”The Political Ec onomy of Banking and Financial Regulation in the U.S.”, pp.
Kroszner, Randall S., (1997b), ”Global Government Securities Markets: The Economics and Politics of Market Microstructure Reforms”, pp.
Kroszner, Randall S., (1998a), ”Rethinking Banking Regulation: A Review of the Historical Evidence”, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Summer:
Kroszner, Randall S., (1998b), ”The Political Ec onomy of Banking and Financial Regulatory Reform in Emerging Markets”, Research in Financial Services 10:
Kroszner, Randall S., (1999), ”Is It Better to Forgive than to Receive? Repudiation of the Gold Indexation Clause in
Kroszner, Randall S., ”Less is More in the New International Financial Architecture”, in W. C. Hunter and G. G. Kaufman, editors, The Asia Crisis: Prospects for Reform, forthcoming.
Kroszner, Randall S. and Raghuram G. Rajan, (1994), ”Is the Glass- Steagall Act Justified? A Study of the U.S. Experience with Universal Banking before 1933”, American Economic Review 84, September:
Kroszner, Randall S. and Raghuram G. Rajan, (1997), ”Organization Structure and Credibility: Evidence from Commercial Bank Securities Activities before the
Kroszner, Randall S. and Philip Strahan, (1996), ”Regulatory Incentives and the Thrift Crisis: Dividends,
Volym D:160 Supplement 25 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Kroszner, Randall S. and Philip Strahan, (1999), ”What Drives Deregulation? Economics and Politics of the Relaxation of Bank Branching Restrictions”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: forthcoming.
Kroszner, Randall S. and Philip E. Strahan, (1999), ”Bankers on Boards: Monitoring, Conflicts of Interest, and Lender Liability”, working paper, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, March.
Kroszner, Randall S. and Thomas Stratmann, (1998), ”Interest Group Competition and the Organization of Congress: Theory and Evidence from Financial Services Political Action Committees”,
American Economic Review 88, December:
Kroszner, Randall S. and Thomas Stratmann, (1997), ”Notes on Development of the Congressional Committee System in the Twentieth Century”, working Paper, University of Chicago, September.
Kroszner, Randall S. and Thomas Stratmann, (1999), ”Does Political Ambiguity Pay? Corporate Campaign Contributions and the Rewards to Legislator Reputation”, working paper, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, January.
Laban, Raul and Federico Sturzengegger, (1994), ”Distributional Conflict, Financial Adaptation, and Delayed Stabilization”,
Economics and Politic, November:
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio
McCubbins, Matthew, Roger Noll, and Barry Weingast, (1988), ”Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies”, Virginia Law Review 78:
McGuire, Martin and Mancur Olson, (1996), ”The Ec onomics of Autocracy and Majority Rule”, Journal of Economic Literature,
March:
Miller, Geoffrey, (1998), ”Political Structure and Corporate Governance: Some Points of Contrast between the United States and England”, Columbia Business Law Review,
Mondino, Guillermo, Frederico Sturzenegger, and Mariano Tommasi, (1992), ”Recurrent High Inflation and Stab ilization: A Dynamic Game”, working paper.
SOU 2000:11 Is The Financial System Politically Independent?… Volym D:161
Niskanen, William, (1971), Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Chicago:
North, Douglass, (1990), ”A Transactions Cost Theory of Politics”,
Journal of Theoretical Politics 2:
Noll, Roger, (1989), ”Comment on Peltzman”, Brookings Papers: Microeconomics,
Olson, Mancur, (1965), The Logic of Collective Action, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Olson, Mancur, (1982), The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities, New Haven: Yale University Press.
Peltzman, Sam, (1976), ”Toward a More General Theory of Regulation”, Journal of Law and Economics 19; 1, April:
Peltzman, Sam, (1984), ”Constituent Interest and C ongressional Voting”, Journal of Law and Economics 27:
Peltzman, Sam, (1989), ”The Ec onomic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation”, Brookings Papers: Microeconomics:
Poole, Keith T. and Howard Rosenthal, (1993), ”The Enduring
Poole, Keith T. and Howard Rosenthal, (1996), ”Are Legislators Ideologues or the Agents of Constituents?”, European Economic Review 40:
Poole, Keith and Howard Rosenthal, (1997), Congress: A Political- Economic History of Roll Call Voting,, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Rajan, Raghuram and Luigi Zingales, (1997), ”The Tyranny of the Inefficient: An Enquiry into the Adverse Consequences of Power Struggles”, Working Paper, University of Chicago.
Rajan, Raghuram and Luigi Zingales, (2000a), ”Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth”, Supplement No. 23 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Rajan, Raghuram and Luigi Zingales, (2000b), ”Politics, Law, and Financial Development”, Supplement No. 24 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Reinhart, Vincent, (1992), ”An Analysis of Potential Treasury Auction Techniques”, Federal Reserve Bulletin, June:
Roe, Mark, (1994), Strong Managers, Weak Owners, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Volym D:162 |
Supplement 25 |
|
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|||
Rodrik, |
Dani, |
(1996), |
”Understanding Ec onomic Policy |
Reform”, |
|||
Journal of Economic Literature, March: |
|
|
|||||
Romano, Roberta, (1997), ”The Political Dynamics of Derivative |
|||||||
Securities |
Regulation”, Yale |
Journal on |
Regulation |
14, Spring: |
|||
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
(1978), |
Corruption: |
A Study |
in |
Political |
Economy, New York: Academic Press.
Sheng, Andrew, (1996), Bank Restructuring: Lessons from the 1980s, Washington: The World Bank.
Shepsle, Kenneth and Barry Weingast, (1995), eds. Positive Theories of Congressional Institution, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Stigler, George J., (1971), ”The Theory of Ec onomic Regulation”, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2; 1, Spring:
Stigler, George J., (1988), Chicago Studies in the Political Economy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Umlauf, S., (1993), ”An Empirical Study of the Mexican Treasury Bill Auction”, Journal of Financial Economics 33; 3:
U.S. Department of Treasury, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, and the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Joint Report on the Government Securities Market, Washington: Government Printing Office, January (1992).
Weingast, Barry R. and William J. Marshall, (1988), ”The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets”, Journal of Political Economy 96, February:
White, Eugene, (1983), The Regulation and Reform of the American Banking System,
Williamson, John, (1994), ed. The Political Economy of Policy Reform, Washington: Institute for International Economics.
Williamson, Oliver, (1996), ”The Politics and Ec onomics of Redistribution and Efficiency”, In The Mechanisms of Governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Wittman, Donald N., (1995), The Myth of Democratic Failure. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
SOU 2000:11 |
Volym D:163 |
|
|
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation?
by
Richard J. Herring*
and
Anthony M. Santomero**
Supplement number 26 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Views, suggestions, and opinions expressed in this study represent the personal views of the authors and not necessarily those of the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
September, 1999
*Jacob Safra Professor of International Banking; Professor of Finance, Department of Finance, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA.
**Richard King Mellon Professor of Finance, Department of Finance, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA.
Volym D:164 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
Table of Contents
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish) ..................................................... |
165 |
|
Executive Summary ............................................................................ |
166 |
|
1 |
Introduction ............................................................................... |
167 |
2 |
Rationales for financial regulation ............................................. |
168 |
2.1 |
Guarding against systemic risk............................................... |
169 |
2.2 |
Protecting consumers ............................................................. |
170 |
2.3 |
Enhancing efficiency.............................................................. |
172 |
2.4 |
Achieving other social objectives............................................ |
174 |
3 |
Why banks have been especially important ............................... |
176 |
4 |
Prudential regulation and supervision: the financial |
|
|
safety net .................................................................................... |
181 |
5 |
Optimal regulation in the static case: pricing risk to counter |
|
|
moral hazard .............................................................................. |
185 |
5.1 |
185 |
|
5.2 |
Prompt corrective action and least cost resolution................... |
186 |
5.3 |
Subordinated debt .................................................................. |
187 |
5.4 |
Narrow bank proposals .......................................................... |
188 |
6 |
Looking beyond the static view: Banks have become less |
|
|
special......................................................................................... |
190 |
7 |
”Optimal” regulation in the transition: some simple |
|
|
prescriptions .............................................................................. |
201 |
References........................................................................................... |
215 |
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:165 |
|
|
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish)
Det grundläggande målet för reglering av finansiell verksamhet är att förebygga s.k. systemrisker, dvs. risken att en störning fortplantar sig på ett sätt som de enskilda aktörerna inte kan hantera och som kan ge stora samhällsekonomiska skadeverkningar. Denna typ av risk hänför sig i första hand till bankerna som dels har en sammansättning av sin balansräkning som gör dem särskilt exponerade för denna typ av risk, dels av tradition utgjort den dominerande delen av det finansiella systemet.
De ”skyddsnät” som etablerats genom olika former av reglering har varit framgångsrika i så måtto att svåra systemkriser kunnat undvikas. Samtidigt skapar dock regleringar även problem, bl.a. när det gäller aktörernas incitament ifråga om rikstagande och riskhantering. Dessa problem kan visserligen i viss utsträckning hanteras på olika sätt, men dilemmat består.
Den teknologiska och marknadsmässiga utvecklingen, främst i USA men även i andra länder, gör dock både att bankerna får en mindre dominerande roll i det finansiella systemet, och att bankerna får en annorlunda ekonomisk och finansiell struktur som gör dem mindre avvikande från andra företag och mindre exponerade för systemrisk. Ur samhällssynpunkt är detta en positiv utveckling som bör underlättas, exempelvis genom anpassning av regelverk och tillsyn, eftersom detta innebär att den speciella regleringen av banksystemet, med de negativa bieffekter detta har, då successivt kan avvecklas.
Volym D:166 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
Executive Summary
The financial system is regulated to achieve a wide variety of purposes. However, the objective that distinguishes financial regulation from other kinds of regulation is that of safeguarding the economy against systemic risk. Concerns regarding systemic risk focus largely on banks, because they traditionally have been viewed as occupying a special role in the economy. The safety nets that have been rigged to protect banks from systemic risk have succeeded in preventing banking panics. However, this success has come at the cost of distorting incentives for risk taking. Regulators have a variety of options to correct this distortion, but none can be relied upon to produce an optimal solution.
Technological and conceptual advances may be ameliorating the problem, nonetheless. Banks are becoming less special. As is evident from the data reported here, the US is leading the way. The trends are apparent in other industrial countries as well. Once banks have lost their special status, financial safety nets may be dismantled thus ending the distortions they create. Ultimately, regulation for prudential purposes may be completely unnecessary. The optimal regulation for safety and soundness purposes may be no regulation at all.
The challenge facing regulators is to facilitate these advances and hasten the end of the special status of banks.
Here, we offer several simple prescriptions to improve financial regulation. First, the authorities should encourage the introduction of technological improvements that are lowering the costs of information and the costs of storing, retrieving and organizing these data. They should be active supporters of competition in the technology and communication sectors.
Second, regulators should resist the temptation to
Third, since market discipline will increasingly substitute for prudential regulation, it is important to assure that both regulation and the regulatory staff are of a quality that is consistent with global standards. In terms of the former, increasing emphasis must be placed on market values throughout the regulatory process, and it is important to improve disclosure standards as well. In terms of the latter, the quality and expertise of the regulation and examination staff must keep pace with the escalating standards of the global marketplace.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:167 |
|
|
1 Introduction***
The financial system is regulated to achieve a wide variety of purposes. However, the objective that distinguishes financial regulation from other kinds of regulation is that of safeguarding the economy against systemic risk. Concerns regarding systemic risk focus largely on banks, which traditionally have been considered to have a special role in the economy. The safety nets that have been rigged to protect banks from systemic risk have succeeded in preventing banking panics, but at the cost of distorting incentives for risk taking. Regulators have a variety of options to correct this distortion, but none can be relied upon to produce an optimal solution.
Technological and conceptual advances may be ameliorating the problem, nonetheless. Banks are becoming less special. The US is leading the way, but the trends are apparent in other industrial countries as well. The challenge facing regulators is to facilitate these advances and hasten the end of the special status of banks. Once banks have lost their special status, financial safety nets may be dismantled thus ending the distortions they create. Ultimately, regulation for prudential purposes may be completely unnecessary. The optimal regulation for safety and soundness purposes may be no regulation at all.
*** An earlier version of this paper was presented at the symposium on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Industry, organized by the Swedish Tercentenary Foundation on March 25, 1999.
Volym D:168 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
2 Rationales for financial regulation
A
Financial markets also provide a crucial source of information that helps coordinate decentralized decisions throughout the economy. Rates of return in financial markets guide households in allocating income between consumption and savings, and in allocating their stock of wealth. Firms rely on financial market prices to inform their choices among investment projects and to determine how such projects should be financed.2
In view of these critical contributions to economic performance it is not surprising that the health of the financial sector is a matter of public policy concern and that nearly all national governments have chosen to regulate the financial sector. Merton (1990) is undoubtedly correct when he argues that the overall objective of regulation of the financial sector should be to ensure that the system functions efficiently in helping to deploy, transfer and allocate resources across time and space under conditions of uncertainty.
However, actual financial regulation attempts to accomplish several objectives beyond facilitating the efficient allocation of resources. In fact, at least four broad rationales for financial regulation may be identified: safeguarding the financial system against systemic risk, protecting consumers from opportunistic behavior, enhancing the efficiency of the financial system, and achieving a broad range of social objectives from increasing home ownership to combating organized crime.
1See Herring and Santomero (1991) for a detailed discussion of the role of the financial sector in a developed economy. For a more recent reference, see Allen and Santomero (1997).
2This is the role emphasized by Merton (1989). See LIewellyn (1999) for discussion of the economic rationale for regulation.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:169 |
|
|
2.1Guarding against systemic risk
Safeguarding financial markets and institutions from shocks that might pose a systemic risk is the prime objective of financial regulation. Systemic risk may be defined as the risk of a sudden, unanticipated event that would damage the financial system to such an extent that economic activity in the wider economy would suffer. Such shocks may originate inside or outside the financial sector and may include the sudden failure of a major participant in the financial system, a technological breakdown at a critical stage of settlements or payments systems, or a political shock such as an invasion or the imposition of exchange controls in an important financial center. Such events can disrupt the normal functioning of financial markets and institutions by destroying the mutual trust that lubricates most financial transactions.
Figure 1. Regulatory measures and regulatory objectives
Regulatory Measures |
Systemic |
Consumer |
Efficiency |
Broader social |
|
Risk |
Protection |
Enhancement |
objectives |
Antitrust enforcement/ ompetition policy
Asset restrictions
Capital adequacy standards
Conduct of business rules
Conflict of interest rules
Customer suitability requirements
Deposit insurance
Disclosure standards
Fit and proper entry tests Interest rate ceilings on deposits Interest rate ceilings on loans Investment requirements Liquidity requirements Reporting requirements for large transactions
Reserve requirements
Restrictions on geographic reach
Restrictions on services and product lines
Adapted from Herring and Litan (1995).
As an examination of the Systemic Risk column of Figure 1 indicates, a substantial number of regulatory measures have been justified on grounds that they help safeguard the financial system from systemic risk. However, research has shown that a number of these measures, such as restrictions on product lines, are ineffectual at best in safeguarding
Volym D:170 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
against systemic risk and may weaken regulated institutions by preventing them from meeting the changing needs of their customers. Some measures, such as interest rate ceilings on deposits that were intended to prevent ”excessive competition”, may actually exacerbate vulnerability to systemic risk. For example, when interest rate ceilings are binding, depositors will have an incentive to shift from bank deposits to assets yielding a market rate of return thus inducing funding problems for banks.
It should be noted also that some regulatory measures work at cross- purposes. For example, geographic restrictions on banking, intended to protect the access to credit of local firms and households, may increase exposure to systemic risk by impeding diversification of regulated institutions and increasing their vulnerability to a local shock. Similarly, the ”fit and proper tests” one might want to impose for safety and soundness reasons may pose entry barriers that are too high to achieve the efficiency gains from competition. We will examine systemic risk and measures to counter systemic risk in greater detail in sections 3 and 4.
2.2Protecting consumers
The second fundamental rationale for financial regulation is the protection of consumers against excessive prices or opportunistic behavior by providers of financial services or participants in financial markets. (See the Consumer Protection column of Figure 1.) Antitrust enforcement is the most obvious policy tool to counter excessive prices.
Competition policy is motivated not only by the concern to protect consumers from monopolistic pricing, but also by the aim of harnessing market forces to enhance the efficiency of the allocation within the financial sector and between the financial sector and the rest of the economy.3
The United States was the first nation to adopt antitrust policy, which, of course, is concerned with monopolistic pricing in all markets not just financial markets. Over the past decade the European Commission has increasingly taken a more activist role in promoting competition. Last year significant attention was focused on substantial price variations within various categories of financial products offered within the European Union.4 Although substantial gains have yet to be
3See section 2.3 for a further discussion of this point.
4See European Commission, 1998.
SOU 2000:11 What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:171
realized, the European Union’s goal of forming a single market in financial services is aimed at increasing competition and lowering prices to users of financial services.
Consumers of financial services – particularly unsophisticated consumers – find it very difficult to evaluate the quality of financial information and services provided to them. In part this is because payment for many financial transactions must often be made in the current period in exchange for benefits that are promised far in the future. But even after the decision is made and financial results are realized, it is difficult to determine whether an unfavorable outcome was the result of bad luck, even though good advice was competently and honestly rendered, or the result of incompetence or dishonesty.
Customers face a problem of asymmetric information in evaluating financial services. Consequently they are vulnerable to (adverse selection), the possibility that a customer will choose an incompetent or dishonest firm for investment or agent for execution of a transaction. They are also vulnerable to (moral hazard), the possibility that firms or agents will put their own interests or those of another customer above those of the customer or even engage in fraud. In short, unsophisticated consumers are vulnerable to incompetence, negligence and fraud.
In order to ease these asymmetric information problems, regulators often establish ”fit and proper tests” for financial firms to affirm their quality (ex ante). And (ex post), it is hoped that strict enforcement of conduct of business rules with civil and criminal sanctions will deter firms from exploiting asymmetric information
The provision of insurance is another response to the asymmetric information problem faced by unsophisticated consumers. One of the rationales for deposit insurance is to protect unsophisticated depositors of modest means who would find it excessively costly to monitor their bank. This is articulated particularly clearly in the Deposit Insurance Directive of the European Union. Other kinds of financial contracts are also insured for the protection of unsophisticated consumers. In the United States, for example, the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation, a
Disclosure requirements also help ameliorate the asymmetric information problem. Investors are often at an informational disadvantage with respect to issuers of securities. Although institutional
Volym D:172 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
investors have the leverage to compel an issuer to disclose relevant data and the expertise to evaluate such data, unsophisticated consumers lack both the leverage and the expertise. For this reason governments have found it useful to standardize accounting practices, require the regular disclosure of data relevant to a firm’s financial prospects and encourage the development of rating agencies, which enable even small investors to take advantage of economies of scale in gathering and analyzing data.
Disclosure concerns also extend to the way in which information is made available to the public. The United States has prohibited insider trading to ensure that corporate officials and owners with better information about the financial prospects of their companies cannot profit at the expense of
Reserve requirements, capital requirements and liquidity requirements designed to ensure that a financial services firm will be able to honor its liabilities to its customers, have a consumer protection (and microprudential) rationale as well as a macroprudential rationale to safeguard the system against systemic risk. In effect, regulators serve a monitoring function on behalf of unsophisticated customers of modest means.
2.3Enhancing efficiency
Competition policy and
However, primary reliance on a firm’s concern for its reputation is not an entirely satisfactory solution to the problem of asymmetric information. Since it takes time to build a reputation for honest dealing,
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:173 |
|
|
primary reliance on reputation to establish the quality of financial firms tends to restrict entry. This may result in higher transactions costs than would prevail in a perfectly competitive market. For this reason establishing ”fit and proper tests” that enable new entrants to affirm their quality ex ante may ease entry and enhance competition, although if entry hurdles are set too high, they will surely compromise efficiency objectives.
The efficient operation of the financial markets depends critically on confidence that financial markets and institutions operate according to rules and procedures that are fair, transparent and place the interests of customers first. This confidence is a public good. It increases flows through financial markets and the effectiveness with which financial markets allocate resources across time and space. But this public good may be underproduced, because the private returns to firms that adhere to strict codes of conduct are likely to be less than the social returns. Unethical firms may be able to free ride on the reputation established by ethical firms and take advantage of the relative ignorance of clients in order to boost profits. The primary efficiency rationale for conduct of business rules and conflict of interest rules is to correct this perverse incentive.
Finally, financial markets provide critical information that helps to coordinate decentralized decisions throughout the economy.5 Prices in financial markets are used by households in allocating income between savings and consumption and in allocating their stock of wealth. These prices also help firms decide which investment projects to select and how they should be financed. Financial markets will provide better price signals and allocate resources more efficiently the better the access of participants to high quality information on a timely basis. This applies not only to information regarding issuers of financial instruments, but also to financial institutions themselves and the products they sell. Disclosure standards thus also serve an efficiency rationale as well as a consumer protection rationale.
Efficiency would also be enhanced if regulators were required to justify each new regulation with a careful assessment of its costs and benefits. This requirement is an obligation of Britain’s new financial services authority. It should be a fundamental part of the regulatory process everywhere.
5 See Santomero and Babbel (1997) Chapters 1 and 2.
Volym D:174 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
2.4Achieving other social objectives
Governments are often tempted to exploit the central role played by the financial sector in modern economies in order to achieve other social purposes. Budget constrained governments frequently use the banking system as a source of
The housing sector is often favored by government intervention in the financial system. For example, the United States has chartered financial institutions with special regulatory privileges that specialize in housing finance. It has also promoted home ownership by extending implicit government guarantees to securities backed by housing mortgages and by allowing homeowners to deduct mortgage interest on their income taxes. In addition, until its interest rate ceilings were eliminated, the United States favored housing lenders by allowing them to pay their depositors a slightly higher interest rate than banks could pay their depositors, a policy that had the effect of enhancing the funds made available to finance housing.
Governments also channel credit to favored uses in other ways. Most countries subsidize financing for exports, sometimes through special guarantees or insurance or through special discount facilities at the central bank. Many countries also require their financial institutions to lend to certain regions or sectors. Since the enactment of the Community Reinvestment Act in 1977, the United States has required its commercial banks and thrift institutions to serve the credit needs of
The United States has also used regulation to achieve the social objective, first articulated by Thomas Jefferson, of preventing large concentrations of political and economic power within the financial sector, especially among banks. Until recently, the United States had restricted the ability of banking organizations to expand across state lines. Restrictions continue against bank participation in nonbanking activities.
Finally, many members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development have imposed reporting requirements on banks and some other financial institutions in an effort to combat money
6 See Santomero (1997b, 1998) for a fuller discussion of this issue.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:175 |
|
|
laundering associated with the drug trade and organized crime. In the United States banks are required to report all currency transactions of $10,000 or more. Currently, Congress is considering even more stringent reporting requirements that have raised serious concerns about violations of privacy rights. Similarly the new Financial Services Authority in the United Kingdom (Davies 1998, p. 2) has adopted the objective of ”preventing … financial businesses being used for the purposes of financial crime”.
Volym D:176 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
3Why banks have been especially important
The preceding survey of the objectives of financial regulation has identified three categories of rationales that apply not only to the financial sector but also to some
However, one motive for financial regulation is distinctive to the financial services industry. Systemic risk motivates a considerable amount of financial regulation but does not apply to regulation in other industries. Moreover, within the financial sector concerns about systemic risk tend to focus on banks. Why are banks especially associated with systemic risk? What’s special about banks?
Many of the products and services provided by contemporary banks are indistinguishable from products and services provided by other kinds of financial institutions. To that extent banks are less special than they once were, a topic we will investigate in section 5. However, the argument that banks are special is based on: the distinctive functions they have performed, the importance of those functions to the economy, and the consequences these functions have had for the vulnerability of their balance sheets to liquidity shocks.
First and foremost, banks have been the principal source of non- market finance to the economy. Banks gather and assess information about prospective borrowers and their investment opportunities. Using specialized human capital and financial technologies7 they screen
7 For a fully developed model of this function, the reader is referred to Diamond (1984), Santomero (1984) and Bhattacharya and Thakor (1993).
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:177 |
|
|
borrowers to identify
On the liability side of their balance sheets banks mobilize savings to fund the loans they originate. The second distinctive function performed by banks is to serve as the principal repository for liquidity in the economy. Banks attract demand deposits by offering safe and reliable payments services and a relatively
In addition to providing sight deposits, banks offer
These functions – making loans, clearing and settling payment transactions, and issuing deposits – are performed more or less simultaneously. Banks transform the
8For a fuller discussion of this role and its effect on the economy, see Herring and Santomero (1991).
9For a discussion of this issue, see Gorton and Pennacchi (1990) and Santomero and Trester (1997).
10See Allen and Gale (1988) for a discussion of the importance of monitoring to project outcomes.
11Goodfriend (1989) and Flannery (1998) make this case quite effectively.
12This point is made theoretically and empirically in Fama (1985).
Volym D:178 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
demand and savings deposits that savers prefer to hold. This asset transformation often involves maturity transformation as well. The consequence of the simultaneous performance of these three functions is that banks have balance sheets that are vulnerable to liquidity shocks. While these functions are usually mutually compatible – indeed, some researchers have argued that banks have an advantage in monitoring loans because they can observe the cash flows of their borrowers through transactions accounts (Black 1975, Fama 1985, and Lewis 1991) – a sudden, unanticipated withdrawal of the deposits that fund
Instability in the banking system can undermine confidence in the financial system and disrupt its role in facilitating the efficient allocation of resources that enhances economic growth. Moreover, it can impose massive costs on society.
From 1980 to 1995 more than
The systemic risk rationale for the prudential regulation and supervision of banks starts from the presumption that the three basic functions that make banking special – loan origination, provision of payment services and deposit issuance – are central to the functioning of the financial system and the real economy, but give rise to bank financial structures that are vulnerable to crises. The opportunity for depositors to run from a bank arises from the fact that deposits must be redeemed at face value on short notice or demand. The motive for a bank run can arise because banks are highly leveraged – with an
13The classic references here are Diamond and Dybvig (1983), and Gorton (1988).
14See Kareken and Wallace (1978), Jacklin (1987), and Santomero (1991) for a fuller discussion of these issues.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:179 |
|
|
illiquid bank assets can cause additional losses, once a run has begun it tends to be
The failure of a nonbank firm is usually not a source of public policy concern in most countries.15 Indeed, the failure of one nonbank firm often improves business prospects for the remaining firms in the industry. In contrast, a shock that damages one bank seriously can spread to other banks. Contagious transmission of shocks may occur because of actual direct exposures to the original shock and/or the failed bank or, more insidiously, because of suspected exposures. In the absence of clear and convincing evidence to the contrary, depositors are likely to suspect that the banks least able to withstand a shock have been damaged. They will attempt to protect themselves by liquidating their deposits at the suspected, weaker banks and reallocating their portfolios in favor of deposit claims on banks perceived to be stronger or claims on the government.16 The result is a flight to quality and a banking panic that destroys not only the specific capital of the banks under pressure, but also diminishes the capacity of the financial sector to fund economically viable projects and monitor them to a satisfactory conclusion.17
When banks fail and markets seize up, they cannot perform their essential function of channeling funds to those offering the most productive investment opportunities. Some firms may lose access to credit. Investment spending may suffer in both quality and quantity. Indeed, if the damage affects the payments system, the shock may also dampen consumption directly. The fear of such an outcome is what motivates policymakers to act.
Prudential regulation and supervision to safeguard against systemic risk arises in the first instance from this externality. While bank managers and shareholders of a bank have appropriate incentives to take account of losses to themselves if their bank should fail – destroyed shareholder value, lost jobs and damaged reputations – they do not have adequate incentives to take account of the potential external costs to other banks and the real economy. Thus they may take riskier positions
15Nevertheless, the failure of very large firm tends to attract governmental attention in most countries because of its impact on employment.
16If depositors withdraw their balances and hold them as cash, bank reserves will contract unless the monetary authority neutralizes the shift. This may be an additional source of contagion.
17See the work of Bernanke and Gertler (1989, 1990) for two similar models of this phenomenon.
Volym D:180 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
than if they were charged a fair market price for such risks. Prudential regulation and supervision is designed to counteract the incentive for excessive
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:181 |
|
|
4Prudential regulation and supervision: the financial safety net
The financial safety net is an elaborate set of institutional mechanisms rigged to safeguard the economy from systemic risk that might result from contagious bank runs. This safety net can be viewed as a series of circuit breakers designed to prevent a shock to one bank from spreading through the system to damage the rest of the financial grid. For our purposes the safety net can be seen as consisting of six circuit breakers that are triggered at various states in the evolution of a banking crisis.18
First, the chartering function seeks to screen out imprudent, incompetent or dishonest bank owners and managers who would take on excessive insolvency exposure. This usually involves fit and proper tests that bank owners and managers must pass to qualify for a banking license. In the aftermath of the collapse of the Bank for Credit and Commerce International, which was engaged in fraud on an international scale, a number of countries established additional tests for continuance of a banking license for foreign banks.
Second, in the event that some financial institution managers do attempt to expose their institutions to excessive insolvency exposure, the prudential supervisory function seeks to prevent it. Prudential supervision is concerned both with leverage and asset quality. Capital adequacy standards, which have been partially harmonized internationally, attempt to constrain leverage risk and ensure that the bank has an adequate buffer against unanticipated losses. Supervisors attempt to control asset risk by
Third, in the event that prudential supervision does not prevent excessive insolvency exposure and a damaging shock occurs, the termination authority attempts to make a regulatory disposition of the bank before it exhausts its net worth and causes losses to depositors. If
18 This safety net is discussed in greater detail in Guttentag and Herring (1989) and Herring and Santomero (1991).
Volym D:182 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
depositors could rely on prompt termination19 before a bank’s equity is exhausted, there would be no incentive to run. But the supervisory authorities face technical and political difficulties in implementing the termination function with such precision. The result is that insolvent banks are often permitted to operate long past the point at which they have exhausted their net worth.
Fourth, if the termination authority acts too late to prevent the bank from exhausting its net worth, deposit insurance may protect depositors from loss and remove the incentive for depositors to run from other banks thought to be in jeopardy. In response to the banking crisis of the Great Depression, the United States established the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation in 1933 to provide insurance against loss for owners of small deposits. Although most other countries have long had systems of implicit deposit insurance, it is only within the last thirty years that other countries have established similar systems of explicit deposit insurance. Although deposit insurance is motivated by concerns for consumer protection as discussed earlier in section 2.2., it may also play an important role in stabilizing the banking system against shocks. The protection is imperfect, however. Even in the US, where the link to financial stability has been most explicit, deposit insurance has been limited, leaving some depositors vulnerable to loss. Thus, the possibility of a run continues.
Fifth, even if runs occur at other institutions, the lender of last resort may enable solvent institutions to meet the claims of liability holders by borrowing against assets rather than selling illiquid assets at firesale prices. Henry Thornton and Walter Bagehot articulated the rationale for the lender of last resort function during the 19th century. Usually the central bank functions as the lender of last resort because it has the resources to intervene credibly to meet any extraordinary demand for domestic liquidity. Although the members of the European Monetary Union have agreed on the powers of the European Central Bank for the conduct of monetary policy, they have not yet agreed on how – or whether – to provide
Sixth, even if the lender of last resort does not lend to solvent but illiquid banks, the monetary authority may protect the system from cumulative collapse by neutralizing any shift in the public's demand for
19 The “termination” of a bank means that the authorities have ended control of the bank by the existing management. Termination may involve merging the bank with another, liquidating it, operating it under new management acceptable to the authorities or some combination of these actions.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:183 |
|
|
cash thus protecting the volume of bank reserves. In this way the monetary authority can prevent any flight to cash from tightening liquidity in the rest of the system. This is precisely what the US monetary authorities failed to do during the Great Depression. But the lesson was not wasted. Most modern monetary authorities are committed to maintaining policy control over the reserve base.
In the major industrialized countries, the various circuit breakers that comprise the financial safety net have been generally successful in preventing a problem at one institution from damaging the system as a whole. In the United States, for example, the safety net which was constructed in the 1930s has virtually eliminated the contagious transmission of shocks from one depository institution to the rest of the system. Similarly in the recent Swedish banking crisis, the Riksbank succeeded in preventing a contagious transmission of shocks to the rest of the financial system and minimized the damage to the real economy.
In effect, banking systems in most market economies operate with the implicit support of their regulatory authorities. With the possible exception of New Zealand, where the authorities have explicitly taken down their safety net for banks,20 the intervention of the regulatory authorities in time of crisis is rationally expected in every market economy. Financial safety nets have reduced the frequency of bank runs, banking panics, and financial disruption. However, these safety nets may have worked too well. Depositors and other creditors have come to rely on their bank’s access to the safety net as a protection against loss with the consequence that they exercise only limited surveillance over riskiness. The pricing of bank liabilities depends heavily on the bank’s presumed access to the safety net. The result is that banks are not penalized for taking greater risks as heavily as they would be if they did not have access to the safety net.21 Consequently, banks take on greater risks.22
This moral hazard feature of the safety net has contributed to the frequency and severity of banking problems, which appear to be rising. In both Eastern Europe and the Far East we have ample evidence of institutions that have assumed excessive risk and suffered severe consequences. As noted above, from 1980 to 1995
20New Zealand’s policy is especially credible because all major banks are owned by foreign residents.
21There are a large number of empirical studies on this point. See Gorton and Santomero (1990), Ellis and Flannery (1992) and Flannery and Sorescu (1996).
22For empirical evidence see Keeley and Furlong (1987, 1991).
Volym D:184 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
example, the real cost of the Savings and Loan crisis in the US has been estimated at less than five percent of GDP, and current estimates for the Japanese economy center are five to ten times this proportion. In less developed economies, where the magnitude of the crisis is even greater and fewer resources are available for resolution, the costs associated with the financial safety net have exceeded the country’s financial capacity.
This has led many to argue that financial regulation and the safety net itself needs some adjustments. Indeed, perhaps the entire approach to regulation needs to be reexamined to find a better way to obtain the benefits associated with a well functioning financial sector, but at a lower cost.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:185 |
|
|
5Optimal regulation in the static case: pricing risk to counter moral hazard
Since the safety net distorts incentives for
5.1
Ideally, the deposit insurer could set risk premiums for deposit insurance that would be identical to the premiums that depositors would demand if the safety net did not exist. In the US, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991 (FDICIA) required that the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) implement a system of
Although the FDIC’s approach was especially crude, it is difficult to see how the ideal system could be implemented effectively. The deposit insurer faces two problems. First, the deposit insurer must be able to measure the bank’s current net worth, evaluate its risk exposure, and
23For example, the differential between
24Kuester and O’Brien (1990), for example, estimated that fair premiums for most firms would be very low, less than 1 basis point, while a few very risky banks had fair premiums in the 1000s of basis points.
Volym D:186 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
assess how the bank’s net worth will vary under alternative scenarios. Such information is not currently available to the regulators and in view of the opacity of most banks, it would be very costly to obtain and verify. Second, the deposit insurer must be able to constrain the ability of the insured bank from increasing its exposure to risk after the deposit premium is set. This would require an ex post adjustment procedure to constrain moral hazard that has yet to be satisfactorily specified.25
5.2Prompt corrective action and least cost resolution
FDICIA implemented yet another
The FDICIA rules are designed to stimulate prompt corrective action as soon as a bank’s capital position deteriorates. The regulatory sanctions become increasingly severe as a bank’s capital position declines from the
25Some researchers have argued that private insurance companies should provide some deposit insurance coverage. But private insurers would face the same challenges that the government insurer faces. Moreover, if the government continues to be concerned about systemic risk, its problem may shift from one of guaranteeing banks to guaranteeing private insurers of banks.
26One of the clear lessons from the S&L debacle in the United States is that losses surge as institutions become decapitalized and shareholders and managers are tempted to gamble for redemption.
27The fundamental analysis underlying this approach to bank regulation may be found in Benston and Kaufman (1988) and Benston et al (1989).
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:187 |
|
|
FDICIA also attempted to end two other sources of distortion implicit in the safety net. The United States, like many other countries, has provided implicit deposit insurance for all depositors at large banks. This subsidy has been provided in two different ways. First is the practice of using purchase and assumption transactions in which the institution purchasing the assets of a failing institution assumes all of its liabilities. FDICIA reduced the scope for these transactions by requiring that the FDIC use the least costly method of resolution under the assumption that its only liability is for explicitly insured deposits.
Second is the practice of extending
FDICIA’s prompt corrective action measures are subject to the same problems as
5.3Subordinated debt
A rule that banks fulfill a specified part of their capital requirements with subordinated debt provides an alternative way to increase market discipline on banks. Subordinated debt is junior to all claims other than equity and so serves as a buffer against losses by the deposit insurer. Subordinated debt has some of the characteristics of ”patient money” because it typically has a maturity greater than one year and cannot be redeemed quickly during a crisis. Subordinated creditors have strong
28 FDICIA called for accounting reforms that would move regulatory measures of capital closer to actual market values, but no real progress has been made.
Volym D:188 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
incentives to monitor bank
The price discipline of traded subordinated debt – which is actively traded in secondary markets – is a much quicker and perhaps more precise way of controlling bank risk taking than regulatory measures which are often blunt and cumbersome to deploy. A falling price of subordinated debt can alert other creditors about the condition of the bank or actions of the managers, creating a broader market reaction. Moreover, market prices are more forward looking than regulatory examinations and may provide regulators with valuable information on the market’s perception of the risk taken by banks (Horvitz 1983).
When bank risk increases unexpectedly, banks may not have to pay higher rates or face possible quantity discipline until their subordinated debt matures. For this reason, subordinated debt proposals generally require that banks stagger the maturities of their subordinated debt so that a modest proportion matures each quarter. In this way market discipline – through price and quantity sanctions – may be effective and informative, but sufficiently limited in magnitude to provide time for crisis resolution or orderly termination.
Critics of subordinated debt requirements emphasize that subordinated debt holders would face the same informational asymmetry problems that the deposit insurer faces, but without the authority to conduct detailed examinations.29 They also question whether secondary markets in subordinated debt would be broad and deep enough to provide reliable price signals.
29 While disclosure practices are endogenously determined, one might expect subordinated debt holders to demand fuller disclosure. As Kane (1995, p. 455) observes “an outside risk sharer must be able to persuade institutional managers to open their books in
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:189 |
|
|
5.4Narrow bank proposals
Another approach to correcting the distortion of incentives that arises from the safety net is to narrow the range of assets that the insured unit of a bank can hold so that the risk to the deposit insurer is essentially zero and so that whatever remaining subsidy inherent in the safety net does not spill out to distort other lines of business. ”Narrow bank” proposals (Litan 1987, Pierce 1991, and Miller 1995) require that insured deposits be invested only in
Alternatively, most of the benefits of the transparency and simplicity of this approach could be maintained, while allowing greater flexibility in portfolio choice, if banks were permitted to hold not only
Critics argue that the narrow bank approach does not address all of the features that make banks special and especially vulnerable to systemic risk. Government might still feel compelled to exercise prudential oversight over the other parts of financial institutions that provide credit to
Volym D:190 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
6Looking beyond the static view: Banks have become less special
The case for prudential regulation of banks to safeguard against systemic risk rests on the argument that banks are special. This stems from their central role as providers of credit, as repositories of liquidity and as custodians of the payment system which gives them a balance sheet structure that is uniquely vulnerable to systemic risk.
Indeed, in most countries, banks retain a central role as the most important providers of credit. (See Figure 2.)
Figure 2. Banks’ share in financial intermediation, 1994
Germany |
77 % |
Japan |
79 % |
Sweden |
79 % |
United States |
23 % |
|
|
Source: Bank for International Settlements, Annual Reports and IMF International Financial Statistics.
The one exception is the United States, where banks have experienced a marked decline in their share of the assets held by the financial sector.30 Although this declining share is often assumed to be a recent phenomenon, in fact the trend was apparent in the 1920s. Indeed, the 1920s were an era much like the last two decades in which the share of assets held by banks declined and that of pension funds trusts and investment companies grew. In the broader historical context the anomaly may have been the relative stability of the bank share of total assets from the 1940s through the
30 Allen and Santomero (1997) present evidence of a trend away from bank finance in other leading countries.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:191 |
|
|
Figure 3. Relative shares of total financial intermediary assets,
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Commercial Banks |
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
50 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
40 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Percent |
30 |
Pension, Trust, and Investment Companies |
|
|
|
|
|
||||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
20 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
10 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Insurance Companies |
|||
|
|
Thrift and Finance Companies |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||||
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1900 |
1910 |
1920 |
1930 |
1940 |
1950 |
1960 |
1970 |
1980 |
1990 |
1994 |
1995 IV |
Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, 1995.
The reasons for this
The impact has been most dramatic on the asset side of banks’ balance sheets. The increased institutionalization of consumer savings, especially in pension plans, life insurance and mutual funds, has given other institutions the scale to assess and diversify credit risk in competition with banks. Improved disclosure standards have made information regarding the creditworthiness of borrowers, which was once the proprietary domain of bankers, publicly available.
Volym D:192 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11
Figure 4. Commercial and industrial loans as a share of
finance, |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Percent |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
90 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
80 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
70 |
|
|
|
|
C & I Loans |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
50 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
40 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
30 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
20 |
Finance Co. Loans |
|
|
|
Commercial Paper |
||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|||
10 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1960 |
1964 |
1968 |
1972 |
1976 |
1980 |
1984 |
1988 |
1992 |
1996 |
|
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
|
|
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, ”Flow of Funds accounts”, 1998.
The decline in the role of banks as intermediators of credit risk has been most pronounced in a US context with regard to business finance as Figure 4 indicates. Banks have lost ground to other, less regulated intermediaries such as finance companies and to securities markets, especially the commercial paper market and the high yield securities market. Indeed, some cynical observers have asserted that the typical bank loan is simply a less liquid,
The decline in business lending is also mirrored in consumer lending. (See Figure 5.) Banks have lost market share to nonbanks such as AT&T, GMAC, GE & Morgan Stanley Dean Witter. Twenty years ago, banks completely dominated the
Increasingly, nonbank,
31 See Business Week, June 12, 1995, p. 70.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:193 |
|
|
Figure 5. Bank market share of credit card receivables,
Percent |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
95 |
92 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
88 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
90 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
84 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
81 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
77 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
80 |
|
|
|
|
|
74 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
70 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
68 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
49,87 |
50,35 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
50 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
40 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
30 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
28,8 |
27,3 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
24,9 |
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
20 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
10 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1986 |
1987 |
1988 |
1989 |
1990 |
1991 |
1992 |
1993 |
1994 |
1995 |
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
|
|
|
|
The growing importance of securitization is especially obvious in the transformation of the traditional mortgage. (See Figure 6.) Formerly, a bank originated, funded and serviced the mortgage until it was repaid. Now one firm may originate the mortgage. Another firm may fund the mortgage or pool the mortgage with others and partition the anticipated flow of income from the pool into marketable securities that will appeal to particular groups of investors around the world. Another firm may insure the pool of mortgages to facilitate this process. The servicing of the mortgage may be allocated to yet another specialist firm that has data processing expertise. The consequence is that mortgages will be funded at lower cost than if firms were obliged to hold mortgages to maturity and what was once an illiquid bank asset is transformed into a highly marketable security. This unbundling can be executed so smoothly that the mortgagee may be entirely unaware that it has taken place. These techniques have been successfully applied to many other kinds of credit transactions including credit card receivables, auto loans, and small business loans.
Volym D:194 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11
Figure 6. Securitized mortgages as a percent of total mortgages,
Percent |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
45 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
40 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
35 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
30 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
25 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
20 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
15 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
10 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1980 |
1982 |
1984 |
1986 |
1988 |
1990 |
1992 |
1994 |
1996 |
1998 |
Year
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of funds accounts,” various years.
Banks are also losing ground on the liability side of their balance sheets. As the baby boom generation matures and inherits wealth, consumer demand will shift from credit products to savings products. This trend is apparent in most industrial countries. In the United States over the next twenty years the population under age 50 will remain the same as it is today, but the population older than 50 will double. The traditional bank entry in the competition for consumer savings – the time and savings account – is deservedly losing ground to mutual funds that have much leaner cost structures and can offer higher returns.32 Bank time and savings deposits have declined steadily relative to
32 See Santomero and Hoffman (1998) for even more evidence of this trend away from banking institutions.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:195 |
|
|
Figure 7. Bank time and savings deposits decline relative to
funds, |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Percent |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
90 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
85 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
80 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
75 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
70 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
65 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1980 |
1982 |
1984 |
1986 |
1988 |
1990 |
1992 |
1994 |
1996 |
|
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
|
|
Source: Investment Company Institute Mutual Fund Fact Book, 1998; and Federal Deposit Insurance Company, Historical Statistics on Banking, 1997.
New technology – often introduced by nonbanks – is jeopardizing even the fundamental role of banks in facilitating payments. (See Figure 8.)
Figure 8. Checkable deposits decline relative to money market mutual fund
shares, |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Percent |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
90 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
85 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
80 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
75 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
70 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
65 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
55 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
50 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1974 |
1976 |
1978 |
1980 |
1982 |
1984 |
1986 |
1988 |
1990 |
1992 |
1994 |
1996 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
|
|
|
Source: Investment Company Institute Mutual Fund Fact Book, 1998; and Federal Deposit Insurance Company, Historical Statistics on Banking, 1997.
Many mutual fund families and most brokerage houses offer cash management accounts that permit individuals to arrange for their salaries to be automatically deposited in their cash management accounts from which routine payments can be made automatically and irregular payments may be made by phone
Volym D:196 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
checks may be drawn on the money market account. In addition, money market accounts can be linked to a credit card that also functions as a debit card at automated teller machines for cash needs. Although payments through the account are cleared through a bank, the role of the bank is a regulatory artifact, not an essential, unique part of the transaction.
Looking ahead, it is not clear how retail customers will want to deal with their banks in the future – or, indeed, whether they will want to
Figure 9. Net interest income less
GDP |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
0,45 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,43 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,41 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,39 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Percent |
0,37 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,35 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,33 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,31 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,29 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,27 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,25 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1977 |
1979 |
1981 |
1983 |
1985 |
1987 |
1989 |
1991 |
1993 |
1995 |
1997 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
|
|
|
Source: Survey of Current Business; and Federal Deposit Insurance Company,
Historical Statistics on Banking, 1997.
deal with banks at all. It is clear that retail customer want ubiquitous access, speed and reliability. Channels for delivery of banking services are proliferating and some
In view of the declining role of the traditional intermediation business, it is not surprising to see the importance of net interest income to both the banking sector and the economy as a whole has fallen in the
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:197 |
|
|
US. (See Figure 9.) Because this decline in the intermediation business is economically motivated and technologically driven, it is likely to be both irreversible, and global in impact.
Although the intermediation business has declined, banks have managed to prosper nonetheless by shifting from traditional intermediation functions to fee producing activities such as the trusts, annuities, mutual funds, mortgage banking, insurance brokerage and
Figure 10. Noninterest income as a percent of financial sector GDP
|
0,2 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,18 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,16 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,14 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Percent |
0,12 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,1 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,08 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,06 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,04 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,02 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1977 |
1979 |
1981 |
1983 |
1985 |
1987 |
1989 |
1991 |
1993 |
1995 |
1997 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
|
|
|
Source: Survey of Current Business; and Federal Deposit Insurance Company,
Historical Statistics on Banking, 1997.
transactions services. (See Figure 10.) Notwithstanding the constraints on allowable bank activities in the US, imposed by the
Overall, banks are holding their own, (see Figure 11), but with a very different configuration of earnings.33 Spread income accounted for about 80 % of bank earnings only a decade ago. Now most large regional and money center banks earn more than half their income from fees and trading income.
33 Boyd and Gertler (1994) emphasized this point.
Volym D:198 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11
Figure 11. Bank value added as a percent of financial sector GDP,
|
0,8 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,7 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,6 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Percent |
0,5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,4 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,3 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,2 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1977 |
1979 |
1981 |
1983 |
1985 |
1987 |
1989 |
1991 |
1993 |
1995 |
1997 |
Year
Source: Survey of Current Business ; and Federal Deposit Insurance Company,
Historical Statistics on Banking, 1997.
The result is that banks are markedly less special in the United States than they were even a decade ago. They are no longer the primary source of business and consumer finance. Neither are they the main repository of liquid savings for the financial system. They do remain custodians of the payment system and for that reason concerns about systemic risk persist. The principal source of concern is what Flannery (1998) has described as
The
34 Australia, New Zealand, Switzerland and the new TARGET system for clearing and settling euro payments operate without permitting participating banks to run overdrafts.
SOU 2000:11 What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:199
exposures to a single counterparty in excess of a bank’s capital. The failure of a counterparty could set off a chain reaction that might bring the whole system to a halt.
This kind of credit exposure is especially insidious. Although it is relatively easy to measure and monitor direct
Under pressure from the regulatory authorities, led by the
In support of these efforts to reduce credit risk in the payments systems central banks in the three largest economic regions have committed to expanding their hours of operation so that payment against payment transactions can take place in bank reserves. Since December 1997, the Federal Reserve has extended the operating hours of Fedwire from 12:30 a.m. to 6:30 p.m. Eastern Standard Time so that it overlaps with the entire European business day and
Volym D:200 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
7:00 p.m. Tokyo Time so that it will overlap Fedwire for
Flannery (1998, p. 30) sees this movement away from a
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:201 |
|
|
7”Optimal” regulation in the transition: some simple prescriptions
Banks everywhere have been subject to intense regulatory oversight and limits, to one degree or another, on allowable activities. Banks in the United States have been subject to relatively tight activity restrictions that have, until quite recently, prevented them from entering many lines of the investment banking business or providing most kinds of insurance to their customers. Nonetheless, they and their counterparts throughout the world have managed to restructure their businesses so that they are much less dependent on traditional intermediation income than they were even a decade ago. As we have seen, most of the large American banks now earn a greater portion of their income in the form of fees and trading revenue with less from spread income.
Figure 12. Relative sources of revenue of major banks
|
|
|
|
Percentage |
||||
|
|
Spread |
Fees |
Ratio |
Spread |
Fees |
Ratio |
Change |
|
Belgium |
1.69 |
.47 |
3.60 |
1.28 |
.50 |
2.57 |
28.76 % |
|
Denmark |
2.76 |
.55 |
5.04 |
3.68 |
.66 |
5.55 |
|
|
Germany |
2.25 |
.56 |
4.04 |
2.11 |
.57 |
3.70 |
8.56 % |
|
France |
2.00 |
.48 |
4.17 |
1.26 |
.90 |
1.40 |
66.49 % |
|
Iceland |
5.97 |
1.78 |
3.35 |
4.76 |
2.22 |
2.14 |
36.13 % |
|
Spain |
3.90 |
.83 |
4.68 |
3.02 |
.93 |
3.24 |
30.80 % |
|
UK |
3.20 |
1.85 |
1.73 |
2.37 |
1.83 |
1.30 |
25.07 % |
|
Sweden |
2.51 |
1.13 |
2.22 |
2.65 |
2.04 |
1.30 |
41.62 % |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
The same trend is apparent for their counterparts throughout Europe and the major OECD nations. Figure 12 illustrates this. Using OECD data, it contrasts the ratio of interest income to fee income over two discreet periods,
Volym D:202 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
European banks by tradition have long been permitted to offer a much broader range of services than their American counterparts. They have been active for some time in underwriting, the direct purchase of equity in the industrial sector, investment management, and a wide array of securities activities. In a recent study of comparative financial systems, Barth, Nolle and Rico (BNR) (1997) illustrate the wide range of bank activity across Europe and around the world. Their comparison across the G10 and other EU nations (replicated here as Figures 13, 14, and 15) illustrates that European banks have broad charters and are fully competitive across the entire range of universal banking products.
Swedish institutions tend to look quite similar to many of their European counterparts. Sweden’s traumatic experience with real estate finance at the beginning of the decade has led Swedish regulators to be somewhat more restrictive with regard to real estate activities than other regulators in Europe and this is presumably the reason for BNR’s designation of the Swedish regulatory regime as ”somewhat restrictive”.
But, in general, Swedish banks may offer a wide array of permissible services and have a broad range of affiliations.
In view of the more liberal regulatory regime in Europe, it is surprising that European banks continue to be relatively heavily reliant on traditional intermediation services. Spread income is still more important to European banks than
In light of this unmistakable trend, what should be the role of financial regulation? Here the message should be clear. If, as we have argued, it is not possible to fully correct the distorted incentives for risk taking that are implicit in the safety net, it is important to facilitate and nurture the trends that will ultimately make the safety net unnecessary. If the safety net cannot be patched adequately, the best course of action may be to advance the conditions under which it may be taken down.
How can this be accomplished, or at least supported by regulating authorities? Here, we offer several simple prescriptions. First, the authorities should encourage the introduction of technological improvements that are lowering the costs of information and the costs of storing, retrieving and organizing these data. They should be active supporters of competition in the technology and communication sectors. These technical advances will intensify international financial
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:203 |
|
|
integration. Already, major investors routinely compare returns across a wide array of international financial arenas, and major borrowers choose from a menu that includes not only traditional domestic sources, but also numerous international alternatives.
Technical advances will accelerate the pace of innovations in financial products and institutions. The ability to call up information cheaply at any time from any location will enable institutions to design new products that will better serve the needs of their customers. This may often be a cheaper substitute for a service provided by a heavily regulated institution and thus will add to pressures to liberalize regulation where it is counterproductive. Institutions will introduce new processes and streamline existing ones. Cheap and easy access to customer data and the application of expert systems will enable financial firms to target particular market segments more efficiently and to distribute multiple financial products at very low marginal cost. Technical innovations will also enable financial firms to assess the profitability and riskiness of each line of business with greater accuracy and timeliness and thus to manage capital more efficiently. As firms employ sophisticated management information systems to determine which lines of business to expand and which to exit, new kinds of financial institutions will inevitably arise.
The second prescription is for regulators to resist the temptation to
In addition, the regulatory authorities will be pressured to exercise forbearance to enable weak firms to adjust to new forces of competition or to support local firms facing aggressive external competition. It is important for the authorities to resist. Not only do such actions create a barrier to entry and maintain excess capacity in the market, but also they
Volym D:204 Supplement 26 |
SOU |
2000:11 |
|
put the deposit insurer and taxpayers at significant risk. Entrenched managers may resist competitive pressures to downsize, streamline or merge, and instead take on riskier projects to try to maintain the size and profitability of their institutions. Since a regulatory response is likely to lag a bank’s actual risk exposures, it could have serious consequences on both the financial sector and the real economy that depends upon it for capital.
Inaddition, the standard competition policies will need to be reassessed.
The conflict of interest rules, and ”fit and proper” entry tests should also be reexamined. Care should be taken to make sure that they are calibrated to accomplish consumer protection objectives and efficiency objectives only. It is important that they not deter new entrants unduly.
Third, since market discipline will increasingly substitute for prudential regulation, it is important to assure that both regulation and the regulatory staff are of a quality that is consistent with global standards. In terms of the former, increasing emphasis must be placed on market values throughout the regulatory process, and it is important to improve disclosure standards as well. Banks should be encouraged, if not required, to report their exposures to risk in terms of the market value of their assets, liabilities and
In terms of the latter, the quality and expertise of the regulation and examination staff must keep pace with the escalating standards of the global marketplace. In many respects the infrastructure of any regulatory regime is the people that enforce and oversee regulations that have been put in place by the political process. In this changing financial sector investments must be made in this infrastructure to insure that the regulatory staff are cognizant of global market trends and are capable of assuring the health of institutions under their regulatory mantle.
The safety net will undoubtedly be subjected to substantial new strains before it can be taken down. The transition will be painful for regulators and for entrenched firms. But, the gain will be a much stronger, more flexible financial system that serves its customers at much lower cost.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:205 |
|
|
Figure 13. Permissible banking activities and bank ownership in selected EU and
Country and Bank Supervisor(s) |
Securities1 |
Insurance2 |
Real Estate3 |
|
France |
Unrestricted; conducted either directly in |
Permitted; sale of insurance products/ services may be |
Permitted; either conducted directly |
|
bank or through subsidiaries. No firewalls |
conducted directly in bank, but underwriting must be done |
in bank or through subsidiaries, but |
||
Credit Institutions Committee, Bank |
||||
mandated. |
through subsidiaries. |
limited to 10% of the bank’s net |
||
Regulatory Commission, and |
||||
|
|
income. |
||
Banking Commission |
|
|
||
|
|
|
||
Germany |
Unrestricted; conducted directly in bank. No |
Restricted; conducted as principal only through insurance |
Permitted; Investments in equity and |
|
firewalls mandated |
subsidiaries, which are supervised by the Insurance |
real estate, calculated at book value, |
||
Federal Banking Supervisory Office |
||||
|
supervisory Office. Insurance regulation does not allow |
may not exceed a bank’s liable |
||
and Deutsche Bundesbank |
|
|||
|
any business other than insurance business being carried |
capital, but unlimited through |
||
|
|
|||
|
|
out by an insurance firm. However, a bank may conduct |
subsidiaries. |
|
|
|
insurance activities as agent without restrictions |
|
|
Italy |
Unrestricted; conducted either directly in bank |
Permitted; sale of insurance products/services may be |
Restricted, generally limited to bank |
|
or through subsidiaries. However, for brokering |
conducted directly in bank, but underwriting must be done |
premises. |
||
Bank of Italy |
||||
and dealing in securities listed on an Italian |
through subsidiaries. |
|
||
|
|
|||
|
exchange other than Italian government and |
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
a special subsidiary. Firewalls are mandated. |
|
|
|
Japan |
Restricted; only bonds (not equities) and only |
Prohibited |
Restricted; generally limited to bank |
|
through securities subsidiaries. A bank can only |
|
premises. |
||
Ministry of Finance (primary responsibility) |
|
|||
own more than 50% of a securities firm with |
|
|
||
and Bank of Japan |
|
|
||
permission from the Ministry of Finance and |
|
|
||
|
|
|
||
|
Fair Trade Commission. Firewalls are |
|
|
|
|
mandated. |
|
|
|
Sweden |
Unrestricted; conducted directly in bank or |
Permitted; bank may only directly sell insurance |
Restricted; generally limited to bank |
|
through subsidiaries. No firewalls mandated. |
products/services. However, both banks and insurance |
premises. |
||
Financial Supervisory Authority |
||||
|
firms are allowed to form “concern constellation” |
|
||
|
|
|
||
|
|
(financial groups) as long as the two activities are |
|
|
|
|
conducted in different firms. |
|
|
United Kingdom |
Unrestricted; conducted either directly in bank |
Permitted; sales of insurance products/services may be |
Unrestricted; conducted either |
|
or through subsidiaries. However, |
conducted directly in bank, but underwriting only through |
directly in bank or through |
||
Bank of England |
||||
market making must be conducted through a |
subsidiaries. However, the bank's investment in the |
subsidiaries. |
||
|
||||
|
subsidiary. No firewalls mandated. |
subsidiary must be deducted from the bank’s capital when |
|
|
|
|
calculating its capital adequacy if the bank ownership share |
|
|
|
|
in the subsidiary exceeds 20%. |
|
Volym D:206 Bilaga 26 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
||||
|
Figure 13. Permissible banking activities and bank ownership in selected EU and |
|
|
||||||
|
Country and Bank Supervisor(s) |
Securities1 |
|
|
Insurance2 |
Real Estate3 |
|
||
|
United States |
Restricted; national |
and |
state |
member banks |
Restricted, banks generally may engage in credit life and |
Restricted; banks generally are |
|
|
|
generally are prohibited |
from |
underwriting or |
disability insurance underwriting and agency activities. |
restricted to investment in premises |
|
|||
|
Federal Reserve System, Comptroller of the |
|
|||||||
|
dealing in corporate debt and equity instruments |
National banks, in addition, bay engage in general |
or that which is necessary for the |
|
|||||
|
Currency, Federal Deposit Insurance |
|
|||||||
|
or securities. They |
may, |
however, |
engage in |
insurance agency activities in towns with less than 5,000 in |
transaction of their business. |
|
||
|
Corporation, and State Authorities |
|
|||||||
|
discount and full service brokerage as well as |
population |
|
|
|||||
|
|
|
|
||||||
|
|
serve as agent for issues in privately placing |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
securities. State |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
to the same restriction as national banks, unless |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
the FDIC determines the activity would not |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
pose a significant risk to the deposit insurance |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
fund. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Bank holding companies may, on a case by case |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
basis, be permitted to underwrite and deal in |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
corporate debt and equity securities through a |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
Section 20 subsidiary so long as the subsidiary’s |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
revenues for these activities do not exceed 10 |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
percent of total gross revenues. Firewalls are |
|
|
|
||||
|
|
mandated. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
European Union 4 |
Not applicable; permissibility is subject to |
Not applicable; permissibility is subject to home country |
Not applicable; permissibility is |
|
||||
|
|
home country authorization and limited host |
regulation |
subject to home country and host |
|
||||
|
|
country regulation, |
primarily |
notification |
|
country regulation. |
|
||
|
|
requirements. (A single EU “passport” exists.) |
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:207 |
|
|
Figure 13. Permissible banking activities and bank ownership in selected EU and
Country and Bank |
Commercial Bank Investment in |
Geographical Branching Restrictions on |
|||
Supervisor(s) |
in Commercial Banks |
Commercial Banks within Country |
|||
|
|
|
Domestic |
Prior Regulatory |
|
|
|
|
Banks |
Banks |
Approval |
|
|
|
|
|
Required |
France |
Unrestricted; Complies with EC Second |
Unrestricted, complies with the EC Second |
None |
None |
No |
Banking Directive. Subject to this |
Banking Directive. 6 |
|
|
|
|
Credit Institutions Committee, Bank |
limitation a bank may own 100% or the |
|
|
|
|
Regulatory Commission, and |
|
|
|
|
|
equity in any |
|
|
|
|
|
Banking Commission |
|
|
|
|
|
Germany |
Unrestricted; Complies with EC Second |
Unrestricted, complies with the EC Second |
None |
None |
No |
Banking Directive. Subject to this limitation a |
Banking Directive. 6 |
|
|
|
|
Federal Banking Supervisory Office |
bank may own 100% or the equity in any non- |
|
|
|
|
and Deutsche Bundesbank |
|
|
|
|
|
financial firm.5 |
|
|
|
|
|
Italy |
Restricted; more restrictive than the EC Second |
Restricted; more restrictive than the EC Second |
None |
None |
No |
Banking Directive. Most banks are subject to an |
Banking Directive. Persons who engage in |
|
|
|
|
Bank of Italy |
|
|
|
||
overall investment limit of 15% of own funds |
significant business activity in sectors other than |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
(7.5% in the case of unlisted firms) and to a |
banking and finance are forbidden from |
|
|
|
|
concentration limit of 3% of own funds in each |
acquiring an equity stake which, when added to |
|
|
|
|
holding in |
those already held, would result in a holding |
|
|
|
|
banks, due to their size and proven stability, are |
exceeding 15% of the voting capital of a bank or |
|
|
|
|
subject to less stringent limits (overall and |
in control of the bank. 6 |
|
|
|
|
concentration limits of respectively 50% and |
|
|
|
|
|
6% or leading banks, and 60% and 15% for |
|
|
|
|
|
specialized banks). Consistency with the |
|
|
|
|
|
principle of separation between banking and |
|
|
|
|
|
commerce is ensured by a further investment |
|
|
|
|
|
limit of 15% of invested firms’ capital for all |
|
|
|
|
|
banks. 5 |
|
|
|
|
Japan |
Restricted; a single bank’s ownership is limited |
Restricted; total investment is limited to firms |
None |
None |
No |
to 5% of a single firm’s shares, including other |
capital or net assets. The |
|
|
|
|
Ministry of Finance (primary |
|
|
|
||
banks (Article 9, |
prohibits establishment of a holding company |
|
|
|
|
responsibility and Bank of Japan |
|
|
|
||
|
whose main business is to control the business |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
activities of other domestic companies through |
|
|
|
|
|
the holding of ownership. |
|
|
|
Volym D:208 Bilaga 26 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Figure 13. Permissible banking activities and bank ownership in selected EU and
Country and Bank |
Commercial Bank Investment in |
Geographical Branching Restrictions on |
||||
Supervisor(s) |
in Commercial Banks |
Commercial Banks within Country |
||||
|
|
|
Domestic |
Prior Regulatory |
||
|
|
|
Banks |
Banks |
Approval |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Required |
|
Sweden |
Restricted; Investments on an aggregated basis |
Restricted; ownership is limited to 50% except |
None |
None |
Yes |
|
are limited to 40% of a bank’s own funds. |
under certain circumstances when a bank is near |
|
|
|
||
Financial Supervisory Authority |
|
|
|
|||
Ownership in a firm is limited to 5% of this |
insolvency and there is a need for external |
|
|
|
||
|
|
|
|
|||
|
base (i.e. 1.5% in a firm or group of firms |
capital injection. In the latter case, greater |
|
|
|
|
|
related to each other). Furthermore, ownership |
ownership may be permitted, based upon |
|
|
|
|
|
in a firm must not exceed 5% of the total voting |
suitability of new owners. 6 |
|
|
|
|
|
power in the firm concerned. These limits do |
|
|
|
|
|
|
not apply when a bank has to protect itself |
|
|
|
|
|
|
against credit losses. In this case the bank must |
|
|
|
|
|
|
sell when market conditions are appropriate.5 |
|
|
|
|
|
United Kingdom |
Unrestricted; complies with the EC Second |
Unrestricted; complies with the EC Second |
None. But need |
None. However, a |
Yes (see adjacent |
|
Banking Directive. Subject to this limitation, a |
Banking Directive. However, a firm would have |
to comply with |
bank must make |
column). |
||
Bank of England |
||||||
bank may own 100% of the equity in any non- |
to make application to the Bank of England to |
the local |
an application to |
|
||
|
|
|||||
|
financial firm. However, an ownership share of |
become a shareholder controller and receive the |
requirements |
open a branch |
|
|
|
more than 20% requires that the investment be |
Bank’s |
and have |
unless passporting |
|
|
|
deducted from the bank’s capital when |
|
adequate |
into the UK under |
|
|
|
calculating its capital adequacy on a risk basis. |
|
systems and |
the EC Second |
|
|
|
Otherwise, the investment is treated as a |
|
controls for the |
Banking Directive. |
|
|
|
commercial loan for the |
|
function. |
|
|
|
United States |
Restricted; national and state member banks |
Restricted; a |
Yes |
Yes; same |
Yes. |
|
generally are prohibited from making direct |
equity investments in banks and bank holding |
|
restrictions that |
|
||
Federal Reserve System, |
|
|
||||
equity investments in voting or nonvoting stock. |
companies. However, the investment must not |
|
apply to domestic |
|
||
Comptroller of the Currency, Federal |
|
|
||||
State |
exceed 25% of the bank’s capital to avoid |
|
banks. |
|
||
Deposit Insurance Corporation, and |
|
|
||||
to investments that are permissible for national |
becoming a bank holding company. In other |
|
|
|
||
State Authorities |
|
|
|
|||
banks. Bank holding companies are limited to |
words, banks may only be acquired by |
|
|
|
||
|
|
|
|
|||
|
an investment not to exceed 25% of a non- |
companies that limit their activities to those |
|
|
|
|
|
financial firm’s capital. |
deemed to be closely related to banking by the |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Federal Reserve Board |
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:209 |
|
|
Figure 13. Permissible banking activities and bank ownership in selected EU and
|
EU Banks |
Domestic |
Prior Regulatory |
||
|
|
|
Banks |
Banks |
Approval |
|
|
|
|
|
Required |
European Union4 |
Unrestricted; the EC Second Banking directive (Article 12) |
Unrestricted; subjects |
None (A single |
Restricted; branches |
|
|
limits “qualifying investments” to no more than 15% of a |
qualifying investments to |
EU “passport” |
are fully regulated by |
|
|
bank’s own funds for investment in a single firm, and to no |
regulatory consent based |
exists.) |
the authorities of the |
|
|
more than 60% for all investment in |
only on the suitability of |
|
EU member state in |
|
|
exceptional circumstances, these limits may be exceeded, but |
shareholders. |
|
which they are situated |
|
|
the amount by which the limits are exceeded must be covered |
|
|
and do not have access |
|
|
by a bank’s own funds and these own funds may not be included |
|
|
to the single EU |
|
|
in the solvency ratio calculation. |
|
|
“passport” to provide |
|
|
A qualifying investment is defined as a direct or indirect |
|
|
services or establish |
|
|
holding in an undertaking equal to at least 10% of its capital or |
|
|
subsidiary branches |
|
|
voting rights or permitting the exercise of significant influence |
|
|
throughout the EU. |
|
|
over its management. |
|
|
|
|
Source: Supervisory authorities in the listed countries provided information used to prepare this table. However, they are not responsible for any errors or misinterpretations. For exact information, one must consult the pertinent laws and regulations in the individual countries. For France and Japan, a source was Institute of International Bankers (1995). Definitions: Unrestricted – A full range of activities in the given category can be conducted directly in the bank.
Permitted – A full range of activities can be conducted, but all or some must be conducted in subsidiaries. Restricted – Less than a full range of activities can be conducted in the bank or subsidiaries
Prohibited – The activity cannot be conducted in either the bank or subsidiaries.
1Securities activities include underwriting, dealing and brokering all kinds of securities and all aspects of the mutual fund business.
2Insurance activities include underwriting and selling insurance products/services as principal and as agent.
3Real Estate activities include investment, development and management.
4The EU members are Austria (January 1, 1995), Belgium (original member), Denmark (January 1, 1973), Finland (January 1, 1995), France (original member), Germany (original member), Greece (January 1, 1981), Ireland (January 1, 1973), Italy (original member), Luxembourg (original member), Portugal (January 1, 1986), Spain (January 1, 1986), Sweden(January 1, 1995), and the United Kingdom (January 1, 1973).
5The EC Second Banking Directive (Article 12) limits “qualifying investments” to no more than 15% of a bank’s own funds for investments in a single
6The EC Second Banking directive (Article 11) subjects qualifying investments to regulatory consent based only on the suitability of shareholders.
Volym D:210 |
Bilaga 26 |
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
Figure 14. Permissible banking activities and bank ownership in the EU and |
||||||||
|
countries: 1995 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Commercial |
Nonfinancial |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Bank |
Firm |
|
|
|
|
|
Securities |
Insurance |
Real Estate |
Investment in |
Investment in |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Nonfinancial |
Commercial |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
firms |
Banks |
|
|
Very Wide Powers |
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Austria |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Switzerland |
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
United Kingdom |
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
France |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Netherlands |
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Wide Powers: |
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Denmark |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Permitted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Finland |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Restricted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Germany |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Restricted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Ireland |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Prohibited |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Luxembourg |
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
Restricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Portugal |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Restricted |
Permitted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Spain |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Restricted |
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
Somewhat Restricted Powers: |
|
|
|
|
|
|||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Italy |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Sweden |
|
|
Unrestricted |
Permitted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Belgium |
|
|
Permitted |
Permitted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Canada |
|
|
Permitted |
Permitted |
Permitted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Greece |
|
|
Permitted |
Permitted |
Restricted |
Unrestricted |
Unrestricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Restricted Powers: |
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Japan |
|
|
Restricted |
Prohibited |
Restricted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
United States |
|
Restricted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
Restricted |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Source: |
Figure 13. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Notes: |
Securities activities include underwriting, dealing and brokering all kinds of securities and all aspects of |
|||||||
|
|
the mutual fund business. |
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
Insurance activities include underwriting and selling insurance products/services as principal and as |
|||||||
|
|
agent. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Real estate activities include investment, development and management. |
|
|
|||||
|
Definitions: |
Unrestricted – A full range of activities in the given category can be c onducted directly in the bank. |
|||||||
|
|
Permitted – a full range of activities can be c onducted, but all or some must be conducted in |
|||||||
|
|
subsidiaries. |
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
Restricted – Less than a full range of activities can be c onducted in the bank or subsidiaries. |
|||||||
|
|
Prohibited – The activity cannot be conducted in either the bank or subsidiaries. |
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? |
Volym D:211 |
|||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Figure 15. Permissible corporate organizational form in which to conduct selected |
||||||
|
bank activities in selected EU and |
|
|
|
|||
|
|
|
|
Securities Activities1 |
|
|
|
|
Country |
Bank Holding |
Directly in |
Bank |
Bank |
Most |
|
|
|
Company |
the Bank |
Subsidiary |
Holding |
Frequently |
|
|
|
Permitted |
|
|
Company |
Conducted in |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Subsidiary |
|
|
|
Austria |
Yes, but |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Bank4 |
|
|
|
infrequently used |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Canada |
No |
No |
Yes |
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Finland |
Yes, but |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Bank |
|
|
|
infrequently used |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Germany |
Yes, but |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Bank |
|
|
|
infrequently used |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Greece |
No8 |
Yes9 |
Yes |
No |
Bank |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Subsidiary |
|
|
Ireland |
Yes, but |
Yes |
Yes |
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
|
infrequently used |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Italy |
Yes, widely used |
Yes |
Yes |
No |
Bank |
|
|
Luxembourg |
No14 |
Yes |
Yes |
No |
Bank |
|
|
Netherlands |
Yes, widely used |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Bank |
|
|
Portugal |
Yes, but |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Bank & Bank |
|
|
|
infrequently used |
|
|
|
Subsidiary |
|
|
Spain |
Yes, but |
Yes |
Yes |
NA |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
|
infrequently |
|
|
|
& Bank |
|
|
|
used |
|
|
|
Subsidiary15 |
|
|
Sweden |
No |
Yes |
Yes |
No |
Bank |
|
|
Switzerland |
Yes, but |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Bank |
|
|
|
infrequently used |
|
|
|
|
|
|
United |
Yes, but |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Varies |
|
|
Kingdom |
infrequently used |
|
|
|
|
|
Volym D:212 Bilaga 26 |
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
|||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Figure 15. Permissible corporate organizational form in which to conduct selected |
||||||
|
bank activities in selected EU and |
|
|
|
|||
|
|
|
Insurance Activities2 |
|
|
||
|
Country |
Directly in the |
Bank |
|
Bank Holding |
Most Frequently |
|
|
|
Bank |
Subsidiary |
|
Company |
Conducted in |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Subsidiary |
|
|
|
Austria |
No |
No |
|
Yes |
Bank Holding |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Company Subsidiary5 |
|
|
Canada |
No |
Yes |
|
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Finland |
Yes & No 6 |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Germany |
No7 |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Greece |
Yes10 |
Yes |
|
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Ireland |
Yes12 |
Yes12 |
|
No |
Bank |
|
|
Italy |
Yes |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary13 |
|
|
Luxembourg |
No |
Yes |
|
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Netherlands |
No |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Holding |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Company Subsidiary |
|
|
Portugal |
Yes |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank & Bank |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Subsidiary |
|
|
Spain |
No |
Yes |
|
NA |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Sweden |
No |
Yes |
|
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Switzerland |
Yes |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
United Kingdom |
Yes |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary16 |
|
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:213 |
||||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Figure 15. Permissible corporate organizational form in which to conduct selected |
||||||
|
bank activities in selected EU and |
|
|
|
|||
|
|
|
Real Estate Activities3 |
|
|
||
|
Country |
Directly in the |
Bank |
|
Bank Holding |
Most Frequently |
|
|
|
Bank |
Subsidiary |
|
Company |
Conducted in |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Subsidiary |
|
|
|
Austria |
Yes |
Yes |
|
NA |
Bank |
|
|
Canada |
Yes |
Yes & No |
|
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Finland |
No |
Yes |
|
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Germany |
Yes |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Greece |
No11 |
Yes |
|
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Ireland |
Yes |
Yes |
|
No |
Bank |
|
|
Italy |
No |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Luxembourg |
Yes |
Yes |
|
No |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Netherlands |
No |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary and |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Bank Holding |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Company Subsidiary |
|
|
Portugal |
No |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Spain |
No |
Yes |
|
NA |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
Sweden |
No |
No |
|
No |
NA |
|
|
Switzerland |
Yes |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Bank Subsidiary |
|
|
United Kingdom |
Yes |
Yes |
|
Yes |
Varies |
|
Source: Office of the Comptroller of the Currency using information provided by bank supervisory authorities in the respective countries.
*
Information as of January 1997.
1
Securities activities include underwriting, dealing and brokering all kinds of securities and all aspects of the mutual fund business.
2
Insurance activities include underwriting and selling insurance products/services as principal and as agent.
3
Real estate activities include investment, development and management.
4
Securities activities fall under the banking activities provisions of Section 1 Austrian Banking Act. Hence, such business may be conducted exclusively by a bank.
5
Insurance activities require a license by the insurance supervisory authority (Ministry of Finance).
6
Insurance activities in Finland may be conducted in the bank as agent but not as principal.
7
Except as agent for insurance companies.
8
Holding companies may own the majority of shares in a Greek bank, but there is no specific legal
framework referring to such companies.
9
10
Only selling insurance products combined with deposits – no insurance risk may be assumed by banks.
11
Excluding investment in bank premises.
12
Only includes selling insurance products and services as agent.
13
Volym D:214 Bilaga 26 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
14
15
16
Pure holding companies are permitted to incorporate under Luxembourg law, but the statute of a bank holding company does not exist. This type of company is not subjected to any prudential control by any authority.
Public debt directly in bank and stock exchange in bank subsidiary.
With the exception of selling insurance as an agent, which is commonly conducted directly in the bank.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:215 |
|
|
References
Allen, F. and D. Gale, (1988), ”Optimal Security Design”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 1(3), p.
Allen, Franklin and Anthony M. Santomero, (1997), ”The Theory of Financial Intermediation”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 21
Bank for International Settlements, (1996), ”Settlement Risk in Foreign Exchange Transactions”, Basle, March (The Allsopp Report).
Bank for International Settlements (1998), ”Reducing Foreign Exchange Settlement Risk: A Progress Report”, Basle, July.
Barth, James R., Daniel E. Nolle, Tara N. Rice, (1997), ”Commercial Banking Structure, Regulation, and Performance: An International Comparison”, Office of the Comptroller of the Currency Working Paper, March.
Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman, (1988), Risk and Solvency Regulation of Depository Institutions: Past Policies and Current Options, Monograph Series in Finance and Economics, New York University, Salomon Center for Graduate School of Business.
Benston, G.J., D. Brumbaugh, J. Guttentag, R. Herring, G. Kaufman, R. Litan, and Ken Scott, (1989), Blueprint for Restructuring America’s Financial Institutions , Washington D.C., The Brookings Institution.
Bernanke, B.S. and M. Gertler, (1989), ”Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations”, American Economic Review, Vol. 1, p. 14- 30.
Bernanke, B.S. and M. Gertler, (1990), ”Financial Frag ility and Economic Performance”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 3, p.
Bhattacharya, S. and A. V. Thakor, ”Contemporary Banking Theory”,
Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 3, 1993, p.
Black, Fischer, (1975), ”Bank Funds Management in an Efficient Market”, Journal of Financial Economics, 2, December, p.
Boyd, John and Mark Gertlter, (1994), ”Are Banks Dead? Or are the Reports Greatly Exaggerated?”, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review, Summer.
Volym D:216 Bilaga 26 SOU 2000:11
Caprio, Gerard, Jr., (1996), ”Bank Regulation: Case of the Missing Model”, Finance and Private Sector Development Division, The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper No. 1574, January.
Davies, Howard, (1998), ”Why Regulate?”, Henry Thornton Lecture, City University Business School, November 4.
Diamond, D. W., (1984), ”Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 51, p.
Diamond, D. W. and P. H. Dybvig, (1983), ”Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 1, p.
Ellis, David M. and Flannery, Mark J., (1992), ”Does the Debt Market Assess Large Banks’ Risk?”, Time Series Evidence from Money Center CDs, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 30 (3), p. 481- 502, December.
European Commission, Communication of the Commission, ”Financial Services: Building a Framework for Action”, October 31, 1998.
Fama, Eugene F., (1985), ”What’s Different About Banks?”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 15, p.
Flannery, Mark J., (1998), ”Modernizing Financial Regulation (Again)”, paper presented at a Conference on Financial Modernization and Regulation, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, September 18.
Flannery, Mark, Sorescu, Sorin M., (1995), ”Evidence of Bank Market Discipline in Subordinated Debenture Yields:
Furlong, Frederick T, Keeley, Michael C., (1987), ”Bank Capital Regulation and Asset Risk”, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review, Vol. 0 (2), p.
Furlong, Frederick T., Keeley, Michael C., (1991), ”Capital Regulation and Bank
Goodfriend, Marvin S., (1989), ”Money, Credit, Banking and Payment System Policy”, in The U.S. Payments System: Efficiency Risk and the Role of the Federal Reserve, edited by D. Humphrey, Kluwer Academic Press.
Gorton, G., (1988), ”Banking Panics and Business Cycles”, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 40, p.
Gorton, G. and G. Pennacchi, (1990), ”Financial Intermediaries and Liquidity Creation”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 45, p.
Gorton, Gary and A. Santomero, Anthony M., (1990), ”Market Discipline and Bank Subordinated Debt”, Journal of Money, Credit & Banking, Vol. 22, (1), p.
Global Derivatives Study Group, (1993), Derivatives: Practices and Principles, Group of Thirty Report.
SOU 2000:11 |
What Is Optimal Financial Regulation? Volym D:217 |
|
|
Guttentag, |
Jack M. and Richard J. Herring, (1988), ”Prudential |
Supervision to Manage Systemic Vulnerability”, Financial Services Industry in the Year 2000: Risk and Efficiency, Proceedings of the Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, p.
Herring, Richard J. and Anthony M. Santomero, (1991), The Role of Financial Structure in Economic Performance, (in Swedish) SNS Forlag, Stockholm.
Humphrey, D. B., ”Payments Finality and Risk of Settlement Failure”,
Technology and the Regulation of Financial Markets, edited by A. Saunders and L.J. White, Lexington: D.C. Heath, 1986,
Jacklin, Charles J., (1987), ”Demand Deposits, Trading Restrictions, and Risk Sharing”, ”Contractual Arrangements for
Kane, Edward J., (1995), ”Three Paradigms for the Role of Capitalization Requirements in Insured Financial Institutions”,
Journal of Banking & Finance, 19, p.
Kareken, John H. and Neil Wallace, (1978), ”Deposit Insurance and Bank Regulation: A
Kuester, K.A. and J.M. O’Brien, (1990), ”Market based deposit insurance premiums”, Proceedings of the Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, p.
Litan, R., (1991), The Revolution in US Finance, Brookings Institution. Herring, Richard J. and Robert E. Litan, (1995), Financial Regulation in the Global Economy, Washington D.C., The Brookings
Institution.
Horvitz, Paul, (1983), ”Deposit Insurance after Deregulation”,
Proceedings of the 9th Annual Conference of the Federal Home Loan Bank of San Francisco, December.
Lewis, M. K., (1991), ”Theory and Practice of the Banking Firm”, in C. Green and D.T. Llewellyn, eds., Survey of Monetary Economics, Vol. 2, London, Blackwell Press.
Litan, Robert E., (1987), What Should Banks Do?, Washington D.C., The Brookings Institution.
Llewellyn, David, (1999), The Economic Rationale for Financial Regulation, Occasional Paper Series 1, London: Financial Services Authority, April.
Merton, Robert C., (1989), ”On the Application of the
Volym D:218 |
Bilaga 26 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
||
Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, Vol. 14, Number 52, July, |
||
p. |
|
|
Merton, |
Robert C., |
(1990), ”The Financial System and Ec onomic |
Performance”, Journal of Financial Services Research, Volume 4, Number 4, (December), p.
Miller, Merton H., (1995), ”Do the M&M propositions apply to banks?”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 19 (June), p.
Pierce, James L., (1991), The Future of Banking, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Santomero, Anthony M., (1997a), ”Deposit Insurance: Do We Need It and Why?”, Ekonomia, Vol. 1 (1), p.
Santomero, Anthony M., (1997b), ”Effective Financial Intermediation”,
Santomero, Anthony M., (1984), ”Modeling the Banking Firm”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 16, Part 2, p.
Santomero, Anthony M., ”The Bank Capital Issue”, Financial Regulations and Monetary Arrangements after 1992, M. Fratianni, C. Wihlborg, T.D. Willet eds., Economic Analysis Series, New Holland Press, 1991.
Santomero, Anthony M., ”The Regulatory and Public Policy Agenda for Effective Intermediation in Post Soviet Economies”, in Financial Sector Reform and Privatization In Transition Economies (7), p.
Santomero, Anthony M. and David Babbel, Financial Markets, Instruments and Institutions, Irwin Publications, 1996, Irwin Publications, 1997.
Santomero, Anthony M. and Paul Hoffman, (1998), ”Life Insurance Firms in the Retirement Market: Is the News All Bad?”, Journal of the American Society of CLU and ChFC, July.
Santomero, Anthony M. and Jeffrey J. Trester, (1998), ”Financial Innovation and Bank Risk Taking,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 35 (1), p.
Santomero, Anthony M. and Jeffrey J. Trester, (1997), ”Structuring Deposit Insurance for a United Europe,” European Financial Management Journal, June.
SOU 2000:11 |
Volym D: 219 |
|
|
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning in Banking with Implications for Sweden
by
Arnoud W. A. Boot*
Supplement number 27 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Views, suggestions, and opinions expressed in this study represent the personal views of the author and not necessarily those of the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
May, 1999
* University of Amsterdam, Faculty of Economics and Econometrics, Finance Group, Roetersstraat 11, 1018 WB, Amsterdam, The Netherlands,
Volym D:220 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Table of Contents
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish) ..................................................... |
221 |
|
1 |
Introduction ............................................................................... |
222 |
2 |
Fundamentals: The Economics of Banking................................ |
225 |
2.1 |
Traditional versus modern banking......................................... |
225 |
2.2 |
Are bank loans special?.......................................................... |
226 |
2.3 |
Securitization: A threat to bank lending? ................................ |
228 |
2.4 |
Is relationship banking at risk?............................................... |
230 |
3 |
Scale and Scope Issues in Banking............................................. |
233 |
4 |
Scope as a Strategic Advantage ................................................. |
239 |
4.1 |
General framework ................................................................ |
239 |
4.2 |
Importance of the competitive environment............................. |
240 |
4.3 |
Is strategic uncertainty special to financial services?............... |
242 |
5 |
Political Considerations ............................................................. |
243 |
6 |
The Future and Implications for Sweden................................... |
245 |
6.1 |
Relevance of strategic options ................................................ |
245 |
6.2 |
Is national identity important? ................................................ |
246 |
6.3 |
What about Sweden? ............................................................. |
247 |
6.4 |
The future.............................................................................. |
251 |
References........................................................................................... |
253 |
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:221 |
|
|
|
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish)
I bilagan görs en genomgång av de faktorer som anses betydelsefulla när det gäller stordriftsfördelar etc. i bankverksamhet och hur detta påverkar strukturomvandlingen. Olika empiriska undersökningar kring detta refereras också. Avslutningsvis förs mot den bakgrunden en diskussion om utvecklingen i den svenska banksektorn.
Bilagan konstaterar att det för närvarande pågår en snabb struktur- omvandling på bankområdet i nästan alla länder, däribland Sverige, med större banker och ökad koncentration som ett viktigt inslag i bilden. Författaren menar dock att denna process bara i begränsad utsträckning kan förklaras med viljan att ta tillvara skalfördelar eller av andra produktionsekonomiska drivkrafter. Den dominerande drivkraften förefaller istället vara en önskan att positionera sig strategiskt i den snabba omvandling som pågår och där osäkerheten om den framtida utvecklingsriktningen och de framtida utvecklingsförutsättningarna är stor. En konsolidering kan här ge ett större manöverutrymme inför kommande faser av strukturförändringar.
Volym D:222 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
1 Introduction
The financial services industry is restructuring and consolidating at an unprecedented pace around the globe. Particularly, in the United States and Western Europe transactions are numerous and breathtaking. But restructuring is also going on in Asia. Most striking is probably the ever- escalating scale of mergers in banking. In just the last few years, in the US mergers have led to a consolidation of money center banks (e.g. the Chase Manhattan and Chemical Bank merger) and the emergence of regional power houses (e.g., the expansion strategies of BankOne and Nationsbank, and their subsequent mergers with, respectively, First Chicago/NBD and BankAmerica). In Europe, mergers have also been prominent. While cross border mergers are relatively infrequent – with exceptions in Scandinavia and the acquisition of the Belgian Bank BBL by the Dutch financial conglomerate ING – mergers between domestic institutions typically involve large universal banks and are often spectacular. Noteworthy examples include the marriage of the Union Bank of Switzerland and Swiss Bank Corporation and the announced merger between Société Général and Paribas (and possibly BNP). And in Japan, a spectacular merger has produced the new
A parallel phenomenon is the broadening of scope of many banks. Even banks that traditionally followed well motivated focused strategies now seem to give in to this trend. For example, Bankers Trust with its activities aimed at the corporate market, now puts itself in the arms of a scope expanding universal bank (Deutsche Bank).
– e.g. ING in the Netherlands – already engage in bancassurance, that is, combining banking and insurance activities. Similarly, Credit Suisse expanded into insurance by acquiring the insurance corporation Winterthur.
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:223 |
|
|
|
One question is then immediate. Why are banks consolidating so much and expanding scope? The popular financial press points to the increasingly competitive environment of banking as the culprit. As commercial banking becomes more competitive, banks need to examine all possible ways to wring inefficiencies out of their cost structures. One way to do this is to merge with other banks and realize efficiencies of scale through elimination of redundant branches and
However, these popular explanations are inadequate. The empirical evidence on scale and scope economies in banking is far from conclusive.1 It is questionable whether these economies are large enough to justify banking consolidation and scope expansion (see Berger [1997] and Berger, et al. [1993]). Moreover, ample research in corporate finance points at the existence of a "diversification discount". On average diversification does seem to destroy value. There is also evidence that improvements in operating performance and stock returns have been experienced by firms that have refocused (see John and Ofek [1995] and Comment and Jarrell [1995]). Therefore, the important question is why are there so many mergers and acquisitions taking place in the industry?
This study aims to address this question and other related issues. I will examine the existing empirical evidence on scope and scale economies in banking. A recent survey paper by Berger, Demsetz and Strahan [1999] is of substantial help. An important question is whether the existing empirical evidence can be used to explain the current consolidation wave. While I will conclude that the existing evidence is of some value, I doubt that it is really helpful for understanding the current restructuring in banking. Several issues play a role here. Apart from econometric and
1 See Shaffer and David [1991], Cornett and Tehranian [1992], Mester [1992], Mitchell and Onvural [1996] and Clark [1996].
Volym D:224 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
the uncertainties and rapid (and unpredictable) changes facing financial institutions today. Consolidation might then be an evolutionary phenomenon and be followed by a new type of repositioning when the uncertainties become more manageable. This analysis follows recent co- authored work with Todd Milbourn and Anjan Thakor (Boot, Milbourn and Thakor [1999]).
The organization of this study is as follows. In Section 2, I start out with a discussion of the growing research in the field of financial intermediation. This research - mainly theoretical in nature – sheds light on the costs and benefits of bank funding
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:225 |
|
|
|
2Fundamentals: The Economics of Banking
2.1Traditional versus modern banking
Traditional commercial banks hold
The banks' assets are illiquid largely because of their information sensitivity. In originating and pricing loans, banks develop proprietary information. Subsequent monitoring of borrowers yields additional private information. The proprietary information inhibits the marketability of these loans. The access to information is the key to understanding the comparative advantage of banks. In many of their activities banks exploit their information and the related network of contacts. This
One might be tempted to interpret modern banking as transaction- oriented. So does an investment bank (IB) – generally considered a prime example of modern banking – facilitate a firm's access to public capital markets. The IB's role could be interpreted as that of a broker; i.e. matching buyers and sellers for the firms' securities. In this interpretation IBs just facilitate transactions, which would confirm the transaction orientation of modern banking. The IBs' added value would then be confined to their networks, i.e. their ability to economize on search or matching costs. As a characterization of modern banking, this would describe their economic role too narrowly. IBs do more. They – almost without exception – underwrite those public issues, i.e. absorb credit and/or placement risk. This brings an IB's role much closer to that of a commercial bank engaged in lending; the processing and absorption of
Volym D:226 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
risk is a typical intermediation function similar to that encountered in traditional bank lending.
In lending, a bank manages and absorbs risk (e.g. credit and liquidity risks) by issuing claims on its total assets with different characteristics then those encountered in its loan portfolio. In financial intermediation theory this is referred to as qualitative asset transformation (see Greenbaum and Thakor [1995]). Underwriting of an IB can be interpreted analogically; risk is (temporarily) absorbed and is channeled through to the claim holders of the IB. The role of IBs is therefore more than just purely brokerage. Underwriting requires information acquisition about the borrower which is supported by a relationship orientation. A relationship orientation will therefore still be present in investment banking, both in the direction of investors ("placement capacity") and towards borrowing firms. Thus, characterizing financial market funding as
2.2Are bank loans special?
Some see public capital market financing as a potentially superior substitute for bank lending. This, however, is unwarranted. Bank lending has distinctive comparative advantages. In particular, it may support enduring close relationships between debtor and financier that may mitigate information asymmetries. This has several components. A borrower might be prepared to reveal proprietary information to its bank, while it would have never disseminated this information to the financial markets (Bhattacharya and Chiesa [1995]). A bank might also be more receptive to information because of its role as enduring and dominant lender. This amounts to observing that a bank might have better incentives to invest in information acquisition. While costly, the substantial stake that it has in the funding of the borrower, and its, hopefully, enduring relationship – with the possibility of information reusability over time – increase the value of information. 2
The
2 Diamond [1984] introduces intermediaries as delegated monitors. See Chan, Greenbaum and Thakor [1986] for a discussion on information reusability, and James [1987] and Lummer and McConnell [1989] for empirical evidence. For a nice illustration supporting the special role of banks, see Berlin [1996].
SOU 2000:11 Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… Volym D:227
particular, relationship finance could allow for more flexibility and possibly
The other dimension is related to the structure of the explicit contracts that banks can write. Bank loans are generally easier to renegotiate than bond issues or other public capital market funding vehicles. The
3See e.g. Simon [1936] and Boot, Greenbaum and Thakor [1993].
4Mayer [1988] and Hellwig [1991] discuss the commitment nature of bank funding. Boot, Thakor and Udell [1991] address the credibility of commitments. Schmeits [1997] formally considers the impact of discretion (flexibility) in bank loan contracts on investment efficiency.
5See Dewatripont and Maskin [1995] on the issue of
Volym D:228 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
insulate the bank from these dreadful consequences. It could now credibly threaten to call the loan, and enforce its wishes upon the borrower. This then identifies an important advantage of bank financing: timely intervention.6
These observations highlight the complementarity of bank lending and capital market funding. Prioritized bank debt facilitates timely intervention. This feature of bank lending is valuable to the firm's bondholders as well. They might find it optimal to grant bank debt priority over their own claims, and in doing so delegate the timely intervention activity to the bank.7 Consequently, the borrower may reduce its total funding cost by accessing both the
The overall conclusion is that bank lending potentially facilitates more informative decisions based on a better exchange of information. While not universally valuable, this suggests a benefit of relationship banking.8
2.3Securitization: A threat to bank lending?
Securitization is an example of a financial innovation – or an innovation in funding technology – that suggests a potential gain of (transaction- oriented) markets at the expense of bank lending. Is this true? Let's first evaluate the economics of securitization.9
Securitization is a process whereby assets are removed from a bank's balance sheet.
6One could ask whether bond holders could be given priority and allocated the task of timely intervention. Note that bond holders are subject to more severe information asymmetries and are generally more dispersed (i.e. have smaller stakes). Both characteristics make them
7The bond holders will obviously ask to be compensated for their subordinated status. This – ignoring the timely intervention effect – is ”a wash”. In other words, the priority (seniority) or subordination features can be priced out. That is, as much as senior debt may appear cheaper (it is less risky), junior, or subordinated debt, will appear more expensive.
8See e.g. Petersen and Rajan [1994] and Houston and James [1995] for empirical evidence.
9Gorton and Pennachi [1995] provide an economic rationale for bank loan sales and securitization. See also Boot and Greenbaum [1995].
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:229 |
|
|
|
example of unbundling of financial services. More specifically, banks would no longer fund those assets, instead the investors buying the asset- backed securities would provide funding. As I will emphasize, securitization does not signal the demise of banks, even if it becomes an economically important innovation (and thus substantially reduces the banks'
The lending function can be decomposed into four more primal activities: origination, funding, servicing and risk processing. Origination subsumes screening prospective borrowers and designing and pricing financial contracts. Funding relates to the provision of financial resources. Servicing involves the collection and remission of payments as well as the monitoring of credits. Risk processing alludes to hedging, diversification and absorption of credit, interest rate, liquidity and
The economics of securitization dictates that the originating bank credit enhances the issue. Credit enhancement is typically achieved through the provision of excess collateral or with a letter of credit. Effectively this means that the originating bank continues to bear part of the consequences (losses) if the securitized assets do not perform. The credit enhancement reduces the riskiness of the
Securitization could lead to a reconfiguration of banking. But even with widespread securitization the incremental value of banks would largely be preserved.11 They would originate and service assets, while
10The reputation of the originating bank will be equally important. Moreover, accreditation by credit rating agencies could also add to the marketability of the securitized claims.
11See also Boyd and Gertler [1994]. They argue that banks have not lost importance. They argue that a substitution from
Volym D:230 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
also processing the attendant risk in order to sustain these activities. Banks would therefore continue to screen and monitor borrowers, design and price financial claims, and provide risk management services.
How important will securitization become? I can only give a very tentative answer. So far, securitization barely exists in Europe. In the US securitization has spread rapidly in the last decade but mainly for car loans, mortgages and
These considerations, however, do not preclude the securitization of business credits. They merely elevate the cost. For example, with more
2.4Is relationship banking at risk?
Relationships may facilitate a continuous flow of information between debtor and creditor which could guarantee a smooth access to funding. Banks’ comparative advantages are often rooted in these relationships. Many believe that a competitive environment may threaten relationships. Borrowers might be tempted to switch to other banks, or to the financial
banks. As in the description of securitization in the text, much of the bank’s value added in the primal activities would be preserved.
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:231 |
|
|
|
market. In particular, increased credit market competition imposes constraints on the ability of borrowers and lenders to
These arguments highlight the negative spiral that may undermine relationship banking. An important observation is that this negative spiral might be
Borrowers, however, face an equal challenge: how to benefit from competitive pricing without jeopardizing the benefits of relationships (see Rajan [1992])? This is the relationship puzzle. The relationship puzzle has no obvious solution. Relationships may foster the exchange of information, but may simultaneously give lenders an information monopoly and undermine competitive pricing.12
As discussed in the preceding subsections, bank lending, securitization of loans and underwriting of public capital market issues may all benefit from a relationship orientation. The distinction between
12The informational monopoly on the ”inside” lender’s side may be smaller if a borrower engages in multiple banking relationships. This would mitigate the possibilities of rent extraction by informed lenders and induce more competitive pricing (see Sharpe [1990] and also Petersen and Rajan [1995].
13A fascinating academic literature is emerging on the design of financial systems. See Allen [1993], Allen and Gale [1995] and Boot and Thakor [1997]. One objective of this literature is to evaluate the pros and cons of
Volym D:232 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
therefore be less
A less competitive financial system may thus preserve relationships more. Competition threatens relationships, but it may simultaneously elevate the importance of relationships as a distinct competitive edge. This is the relationship paradox. A relationship orientation can alleviate competitive pressures. Thus, a more competitive environment should encourage banks to become
14 Boot and Thakor [1999] develop this intuition further. They show that competition may indeed induce banks to divert resources to relationship- specific activities. In their model banks choose between ‘passive’ transaction lending and more intensive relationship lending. Transaction lending competes
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:233 |
|
|
|
3 Scale and Scope Issues in Banking
Scale and scope economies are often cited as one of the main reasons behind the current merger and acquisition wave in banking. Are scale and scope economies present? And could they rationalize the current restructuring in the industry? Scale and scope economies in banking have been studied extensively. In general, the empirical evidence cannot readily identify substantial economies of scale or scope. Scale economies could not be found beyond a relatively small size of banks as measured by total assets (i.e., beyond $ 100 million up to $ 10 billion in total assets), see Table 1. Only recently have some studies succeeded in showing some economies of scale at a level of total assets up to $ 25 billion. Similar results were obtained for scope economies. These results seem hard to reconcile with the perceived wisdom of bankers and the observed
Most empirical researchers in the area of industrial organization will acknowledge that scale and scope economies are difficult to measure. So, at best, very modest conclusions could ever be drawn from these empirical studies. With this in mind, we can start analyzing the evidence. A first observation is that the inconclusive results are not really surprising. Inefficiencies in managing larger organizations may mitigate possible scale and scope benefits. This would be in line with the sizable literature on the "diversification discount". A complication is also that increasing scale and scope may facilitate market power and thus elevate profitability in absence of scale and scope economies. This effect might be less important in
Volym D:234 Supplement 27 |
|
SOU 2000:11 |
||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Table 1. The empirical evidence on scale and scope economies |
|
|
|
||
|
Subject |
|
Main findings |
|
|
|
|
• Market power analysis: effect on prices and profits |
|
|
|
||
|
Static |
|
Higher rates on small business loans, lower deposit rates |
|
||
|
° |
|
||||
|
|
° Effect on deposit rates has become less in the 90’s |
|
|
|
|
|
|
° Deposit rates sticky (show downward rigidity) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
° |
|
|||
|
|
° Small effect of concentration on bank profits |
|
|
|
|
|
|
° |
Most profitable banks are not in most concentrated |
|
||
|
|
|
markets |
|
|
|
|
Dynamic |
|
|
|
|
|
|
(effect of M&A) |
° |
Downward effect on deposit rates if related to increase in |
|
||
|
|
|
concentration |
|
|
|
|
|
° Effect on profitability ratio’s mixed, but possibly positive |
|
|||
|
|
° Event studies show mixed results on combined value of |
|
|||
|
|
|
target and acquirer: but focus (both geographic and |
|
||
|
|
|
activity) adds value. International mergers more profitable |
|
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
• Efficiency consequences |
|
|
|
||
|
Static |
|
Main focus on |
|
||
|
° |
|
||||
|
|
|
between $ 100 million and $ 10 billion in total assets |
|
||
|
|
° Scope economies studies find similar results |
to |
scale |
|
|
|
|
|
economies studies |
|
|
|
|
|
° Recent 1990’s studies find greater potential |
of |
scale |
|
|
|
|
|
economies (up to $ 25 billion in total assets, but possibly |
|
||
|
|
|
beyond) |
|
|
|
|
|
° Potential for scale, scope and product mix efficiencies in |
|
|||
|
|
|
managing risk, particularly diversification benefits of |
|
||
|
|
|
geographical expansion |
|
|
|
|
|
° Combining bank and |
|
|||
|
|
|
mixed effect on total risk |
|
|
|
|
Dynamic |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
° Cost efficiency (controlled for market power |
effects) |
|
||
|
|
|
shows little improvement |
|
|
|
|
|
° Efficiency gains in US |
|
|||
|
|
|
market mergers |
|
|
|
|
|
° Some diversification benefits: higher proportion of loans |
|
|||
|
|
|
per dollar of capital (at expense of securities holdings) |
|
||
|
Source: Berger, Demsetz and Strahan [1999]. |
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:235 |
|
|
|
Several other qualifications should be made. First, most studies concern the US Contrary to banking in many other countries, US banking has historically been quite fragmented.15 The mergers and acquisitions that were included in most studies (mostly dating back to the 70’s and 80’s) took place in an environment where severe constraints existed on the type and geographic dispersion of activities. It is conceivable that these restrictions made it difficult to benefit from scale and scope economies (see also Calomiris and Karceski [1997]).
Second, the level of aggregation in most studies may obscure benefits to scale and scope. In particular, we should look at what type of mergers and acquisitions involve scale and/or scope benefits. For example, Flannery [1999] points at recent research that suggests that mergers with both a geographic and activity focus are most value enhancing.16 Similarly, in analyzing scope and scale issues we should focus on the type of activities. What are the scale economies in each activity? And what
These observations offer yet little proof for true scale and scope economies. I see the following five primary sources of scale and scope economies (see also Canals [1994]):18
15This is not really surprising. U.S. banks face(d) substantial regulatory constraints on their activities concerning both the type of their activities (e.g. banks could engage in commercial banking or investment banking, not both) and their location (e.g. limits on interstate banking). More recently, however, regulatory constraints have become less binding. This undoubtedly partially explains the surge in mergers and acquisitions.
16An important issue is whether this only points at
17Surprisingly, this type of research is yet hard to find. A lot of research has been done on potential conflicts of interest in universal banking. To some extent, this is activity specific (investment banking versus commercial banking). However, this research is of very limited interest because it ignores the question of complementarity between activities. This is not really surprising because the literature is solely motivated by the obscure Glass- Steagall regulation in the U.S. (see Kroszner and Rajan [1994] and Puri [1996]).
18Observe that some of these sources of scope and scale economies are inter- related.
Volym D:236 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
i.Information technology related economies;
ii.
iii.Marketing/brand name and reputation related benefits;
iv.
v.Benefits of diversification
Table 2. Some problems with the existing empirical studies on scale and scope
economies
Subject |
|
|
|
Issues |
|
|
|
|
• Market power analysis: effect on prices and profits |
|
|
|
|
||||
Static |
|
Is concentration the |
right |
measure? |
What about |
|||
|
° |
|||||||
|
|
|
contestability of markets? |
|
|
|
||
Dynamic |
|
° Combined effect of market power and efficiency |
||||||
(effect of M&A) |
|
|
changes difficult to disentangle |
|
|
|||
|
|
° Profitability ratio’s affected by market power |
||||||
|
|
° Cost ratio’s via costs of deposits linked to market |
||||||
|
|
|
power. |
Operational |
costs |
affected |
by |
relative |
|
|
|
importance of deposits versus purchased funds |
|||||
|
|
° Event |
studies affected by "signaling". That is, the |
|||||
|
|
|
immediate effect of a merger announcement on stock |
|||||
|
|
|
prices incorporates all types of changes in |
|||||
|
|
|
expectations |
|
|
|
|
|
• Efficiency consequences |
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
Static |
|
° How to measure scope economies |
|
|
||||
|
|
|
||||||
|
|
° Lack of data points for |
|
|||||
Dynamic |
|
° |
Little |
differentiation |
between type |
of |
merger |
|
|
|
|
and/or type of activities |
|
|
|
The first source, information technology, is potentially of great importance. Most of the existing studies on scale and scope economies involve data that precede the information technology revolution. It is likely that recent information technology developments facilitate a much more efficient and effective utilization of information over ranges of services and customers. That is,
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:237 |
|
|
|
facilitate differentiation of products and services.19 Together with the sizable investments projected in information technology, scale and scope benefits may have become more important. The implication is also that sizable investments in information technology are needed to truly benefit from scale and scope economies. This relates also to the second source: distribution network related benefits may be rooted in information technology developments. In particular, IT developments may facilitate scale economies offering gains in running a sizable distribution network.
The next source of scale and scope economies is linked to marketing and reputation. Marketing expenses involve substantial fixed costs. This suggests some economies of scale. Also, scope benefits may be present in the joint marketing of products to customers. Brand image is partially marketing related but is also linked to the notions of "trust", "reputation" and "confidence". These notions play an important role in the financial services industry. Increasingly, financial service providers offer services that crucially depend on their reputation. For example, the growing importance of
The next source of potential scale and scope economies is financial innovation. Financial innovation as a source of scope and scale economies is a
The last potential source of scale and scope economies is the benefit of diversification. From a corporate finance perspective, this benefit is controversial. After all, investors (shareholders) could diversify and why
19 In Section 2.4, I have discussed the effect of increasing competition on the reusability of information. The conclusion there was that
Volym D:238 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
would a financial institution itself need to do this? But, nevertheless, low variability of returns is considered very important in banking.
My assessment is that scale and scope economies are present. However, the complexity of running the larger organizations needed to exploit these are far from trivial. I would expect, therefore, that the empirical evidence in a
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:239 |
|
|
|
4 Scope as a Strategic Advantage
4.1General framework
The explanation developed in this section is that strategic uncertainty about future exploitable core competencies may dictate broadening of scope. The basic idea is as follows. Suppose a bank knows that – perhaps due to deregulation – it can participate in a
One can explain scope expansion as the bank reserving the right to play in a variety of "new" activities. By making incremental investment today, the bank puts itself in a privileged position through the acquisition of superior information by learning. This allows the bank to wait until the environment becomes less uncertain before determining whether to compete in the new market and if so, how aggressively; see also Courtney et al. [1997] for the link between strategy and uncertainty.
In a recent paper (see Boot, Milbourn and Thakor [1999]) a formal model of banking has been developed that formalizes these ideas and incorporates scope as a potential competitive advantage. The framework in that paper is as follows. It starts out with a banking sector with narrowly defined existing activities and asks whether banks should expand into a "new" activity. A key feature of the analysis is that there is strategic future uncertainty about the demand for this new activity, i.e. the activity has prospects only in the long run and demand may not
Volym D:240 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
materialize. The bank must decide whether or not to expand in this activity, and if so, whether to enter early or late. Early entry is costly because the activity becomes important only later. Demand may not materialize, and entering early requires investments to be made prior to the resolution of demand uncertainty. Moreover, the scope expansion associated with investing in strategic options could reduce the competitiveness of existing operations (say due to dilution of focus). However, early entry offers potential strategic advantages. In particular, early entry could lead to the discovery of skills that would allow for a more efficient delivery of the new activity and hence make the commercial bank a more credible competitor once the prospects of this activity become clear.
The question is: when will the benefits of early entry outweigh the costs? The uncertainty about skills plays a key role here. If this uncertainty is substantial, early entry may be beneficial. The other key factor is the competitive environment of the banking sector, and the anticipated competition for the new activity. Suppose that the new activity can also be offered by a specialized provider (a "boutique" specializing in this activity). If the commercial bank enters (early or late), we could consider the market for this activity as a Cournot duopoly game. Early entry is beneficial because the bank would then learn its skills in the new activity. This allows the bank to compete more aggressively when it has favorable information about its skills and more cautiously when it has poor information about its skills. The benefits of early entry also depend on how likely it is that a specialized provider will come along. Whether early entry is optimal will thus crucially depend on the competitive environment.
4.2Importance of the competitive environment
Also the competitive environment of the existing banking activities enters the analysis because of the investment and risk associated with early entry in the new activity. If banking is sufficiently competitive, banks would be unable to absorb the investment and risk that come with early entry. An immediate implication is that investments in strategic options and thus the adoption of broader,
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:241 |
|
|
|
local market power allows them to afford the "widening of scope" strategy and benefit from its potential future strategic advantages.
Moreover, as stated earlier, the anticipated future competitive environment for the new activity matters as well. If the bank anticipates facing little or no competition in this activity in the future, early entry – with its accompanying cost of focus dilution – is unnecessary because a competitively unchallenged bank can operate successfully in this market without the benefit of early skills discovery. At the other extreme, when the anticipated competition for the new activity is very intense (perhaps due to many potential future competitors), early entry may once again be
Table 3. Optimal scope as function of the competitive environment
Anticipated competitive environment |
Current competitive environment in |
|
in the strategic option (new activity) |
existing banking activities |
|
|
Little competition |
High competition |
Little competition |
Narrow |
Narrow |
Medium competition |
Broad |
Narrow |
High competition |
Narrow |
Narrow |
(Narrow - no early investment in new activity, Broad - early investment in new activity)
The analysis shows that the competition in the bank’s current activity, the competition it anticipates in the future in a new activity, and the degree of uncertainty about future skills needed in the new activity combine to lead to predictions about early entry and hence optimal scope. Scope expansion is seen to be optimal when there is high strategic uncertainty, moderate competition expected in the new activity, and low-
In this context also the benefits of consolidation could be explored. Now assume that there are multiple competing banks at the outset. Consider two of these banks contemplating a merger. The question before them is whether consolidation (merging) today gives them a competitive advantage in undertaking the new activity tomorrow. Boot, Milbourn and Thakor [1999] show that the benefit of such a merger is twofold. First, merging may help create "deep pockets" making investments in strategic options more affordable. Second, merging leads to diversification in skills. The two banks jointly have a higher probability of having the right skills to compete in the new activity than
Volym D:242 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
each has separately. While both effects may work in concert in many mergers, either effect by itself could rationalize a merger.
It should be clear that these effects have little significance in an environment without strategic uncertainty. The analysis thus predicts greater consolidation in industries with more strategic uncertainty.
4.3Is strategic uncertainty special to financial services?
Why does this model of strategic uncertainty fit banking so well? There are at least three reasons. First, deregulation in financial services is opening doors to new activities for banks at a rate that is unprecedented since the Great Depression. Second, the swirling tides of technological and regulatory changes are generating a level of uncertainty about the skills needed to operate successfully in the future that is perhaps greater in banking than in any other industry. Lastly, banks have traditionally faced limited competition in their home markets. This has created "deep pockets" across the industry, and serves to support the broad strategies observed in banking. In particular, the combined validity of these arguments makes the model especially suited for the banking industry.20
The precise interpretation of the model of strategic uncertainty could also be amended to fit banking even better. In particular, we could interpret the bank’s problem as the bank not knowing what combination of activities will give it a competitive edge in the future. Now we would not necessarily be talking about a bank entering new activities but possibly about the bank entering "old" activities that it traditionally chose to abstain from. Early entry, or better, choosing a wider set of activities would let the bank discover what activities optimally fit together. This interpretation would be fully consistent with the analysis in Boot, Milbourn and Thakor [1999].
20 However, this does not limit the applicability of our model. In fact, any industry with similar characteristics to those given above – such as pharmaceuticals or telecommunications – is amenable to the interpretations and insights provided.
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:243 |
|
|
|
5 Political Considerations
I will discuss political considerations in the context of differences between the banking industry in Europe and the US In both, government interference has been quite dominant. Consolidation has been observed in Europe already for some time and in the US more recently. But is there really something to be learned from the European experience, or from the American experience for that matter? And are experiences across continents and countries comparable? In a recent paper on corporate governance, Jon Macey and I describe one of the big fallacies in comparing models of corporate governance. We say "the rhetoric about corporate governance appears to us to be divorced from reality in that two paradigmatic governance systems – the German model and the US model – are not really models at all. […] The German model is not even
a model for the rest of Europe" (Boot and Macey [1998]). I feel the same in the context of discussing European or American trends. Of course, some obvious lessons can be learned. For example, the more consolidated financial sector observed in Europe gives a clear hint about what can be expected in US banking when regulatory constraints become less binding (as they have become in recent years). But what can be said more fundamentally about the diverse European experience? And what can be learned from the US experience?
Let me first focus on the arguable superficial common European experience as it may relate to the US Europe and the US share some similar dynamics. In particular, the relaxation of constraints on interstate banking in the US is reminiscent of the European Union banking directives liberating
The political dimension is at the root of this. Even in countries that do not have any direct interference by governments in banking operations and where banks are considered truly commercial enterprises (and have generally been successful, e.g. ABN AMRO and ING in The Netherlands), the political dimension is important. Central banks, ministries of finance and the banks operate in close concert. This is not very surprising: a very homogeneous group of executives is in charge of the financial sector, central bank and government ministries guaranteeing
Volym D:244 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
a clear national identity of domestic institutions. In countries with explicit government involvement (e.g. France and Italy), foreign control over domestic institutions is even more unlikely unless banks become so inefficient and weak that involvement of foreigners becomes almost inevitable. To some extent this is happening. For example, in the recent bidding war for the French bank CIC, ABN AMRO was favored by some because of its excellent track record
The primary response to the liberating E.U. directives has so far been defensive: domestic mergers are generally encouraged to protect national interests. A case in point is Germany. Many have observed that banking in that country is surprisingly dispersed despite the powerful images of Deutsche Bank, Commerzbank and Dresdner Bank. Public policy definitely aims at protecting the interests of these powerful institutions, but the consolidation is played out mainly on the
So, wherever we look in Europe, I dare to conclude that the national flagship dimension has been of primary importance. Cross border expansion is rare and consolidation is primarily observed within national borders. For the US this gives little direction. Interstate expansion has been a driving force behind the consolidation in US banking. Politics does now seem to interfere little with interstate expansion. The political dimension in the US seems focused on the demarcations between commercial banking, investment banking and insurance. Powerful lobbies are successful in mobilizing (local) politicians and in this way have been able to obstruct major banking reform in the US Congress.
In other words, in both the US and Europe vested interests are at work. In Europe there are national authorities preserving their national flagships, in the US, powerful lobbies that seek to preserve traditional demarcations between financial institutions. These observations do not yet answer the question whether national (European) authorities are serving the interests of their constituencies when advocating national flagships. This is a different issue, and may have to be looked at in a
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:245 |
|
|
|
6The Future and Implications for Sweden
6.1Relevance of strategic options
Let me highlight a broader interpretation of the strategic option explanation in Boot, Milbourn and Thakor [1999] in the context of the restructuring of the European financial services industry. Bankers strongly belief that a strong position in the home market is crucial for a successful expansion in foreign markets. Generally, this seems to be the case. I will give a few examples. Belgian banks have weak foreign operations: the Belgian political situation (the split between the French and Dutch speaking regions) did not allow for strong domestic powerhouses. Swedish and other Scandinavian banks suffered from a financial crisis in the late eighties, early nineties inhibiting their foreign aspirations. Spanish banks started to consolidate "late". Their foreign aspirations seem limited, but some (e.g. Santander) choose to expand in the South American market (with some success). The Dutch, Swiss and
– to a lesser extent – German powerhouses have strong franchises in their home markets and may well be the only Continental European banks with credible foreign aspirations.21
In the interpretation of the Boot, Milbourn and Thakor [1999] paper, strength in the home markets allows banks to invest in strategic options. An important one is investment banking (IB). While Continental European banks traditionally dominated the domestic activity in investment banking, they have had a more marginal role in IB in foreign markets and now also face severe competition in their domestic IB activity. Many of them feel that a presence in IB might be important for their existence as powerful banks in the future. They are willing to accept – for the moment at least – relatively low returns on those activities. The potential but uncertain vital role of these activities in the future defines them as a strategic option.
21 I deliberately leave out the U.K. banks whose prospects are mixed, but definitely have a strong potential. One of my more favorable consolidation scenario’s would involve
Volym D:246 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
From a shareholder value maximization point of view, investing in strategic options might be desirable (if at least potentially sufficiently lucrative). However, how can we distinguish the "strategic option" explanation from a simple managerial entrenchment explanation? That is, managers (and governments!) may just want powerful institutions for their own sake. Distinguishing between those explanations is difficult. As the experiences of the French bank Credit Lyonnais teach us, banks that are not accountable, and even worse, operate as playground for
Banks themselves are ambivalent too. The struggle of European banks in investment banking is a perfect example: while some see it as a strategic option, others (NatWest and Barclays) have retreated, albeit not really voluntarily! We see a similar ambivalence
Nevertheless, as attested to in Section 3, I do believe that scale and scope economies are present in banking. I am tempted to subscribe to Calomiris and Karceski’s [1998] notion of "client based universal banking strategies" where a bank seeks to optimally service its client base by choosing the appropriate products, services and geographical presence. Simultaneously, however, I observe that much of the consolidation in European banking is defensive. Consolidation has increased scale and scope mainly in domestic markets and facilitated local market power. Size has reached proportions that seriously questions whether anymore benefits of scale are present. And is the wider scope truly sustainable? Will it not cause dilution and loss of focus? If so, it will clearly limit the desirability of investing in strategic options. Instructive in this respect is that the operations of European universal banks in foreign markets (where they face more competition) are generally
6.2Is national identity important?
I would not dare to say that the national identity or ownership of financial institutions does not matter, albeit as
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:247 |
|
|
|
facilitate their healthy growth and development. But favoritism should not always be excluded.
6.3What about Sweden?
I list five categories of issues: i. important considerations for the Swedish financial sector, ii. main strengths of financial institutions, iii. weaknesses and concerns, iv. options for the future, and v. the value of alliances.
i. Important considerations
•An important distinction needs to be made between the viability of existing financial institutions in the Swedish or Scandinavian market and the likelihood that existing institutions will preserve their independence (and remain or become national flagships) in the future. Swedish banks seem ahead in the Nordic market. An noteworthy exception is the challenge by Den Danske Bank, the largest bank in Denmark that bought the Swedish regional bank Östgöta Enskilda Bank;
•Swedish banks have followed very diverse repositioning strategies, e.g. Svenska Handelsbanken (main focus: retail (mainly in Sweden) and some corporate and investment banking in Nordic market; recent merger with local mortgage lender Stadshypotek), FöreningsSparbanken (main focus: retail in local Swedish market; result of merger between Sparbanken Sverige and Föreningsbanken), Merita Nordbanken (main focus:
•Investment banking in Nordic market is truly international with a sizable market share by foreign
•Strong Nordification of financial institutions. Little
•"Fortress Scandinavia" is to some extent being created, see also Stockholm Exchange that has chosen not to participate in the pan- European cooperation of major stock exchanges.
ii. Strengths of Swedish financial institutions
The Swedish financial institutions have recovered remarkably from the banking crisis of the early 1990’s. In terms of efficiency numbers,
Volym D:248 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
profitability and capitalization, they belong to the top of European financial institutions. Their strengths could be summarized as follows.
•high capitalization;
•cost efficient;
•high return on equity;
•leading in Nordic countries;
•culturally adapt, strong relationships with customers.
These strengths should not lead to complacency by Swedish financial institutions. Major challenges lie ahead.
iii. Weaknesses and main concerns
•small home market. The scale of operations that can be obtained within the Nordic market is relatively small;
•limited geographical diversification (Nordic market at best);
•(risk of) lack of true international perspective;
•main profitability comes from traditional commercial banking activities;22
•potential mismatch between regional orientation of banks and international orientation of the major industrial Nordic corporations;
•risk of new distribution channels. More specifically, direct banking by new entrants (possibly linked to asset management firms) could pose a threat;23
A general concern is that the regional orientation of Nordic banks potentially insulates them from new innovations. What I mean with this is that the lack of international presence reduces the possibility of "importing" innovations and/or practices from other markets. This is a serious concern. The experience is that
iv. Options
•Geographic segmentation of financial services will not adhere to Nordic borders. If autonomy of Nordic financial institutions is an
22This actually is partially a strength too, because it also points at capitalizing on strong relationships.
23One should not
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:249 |
|
|
|
objective, alliances with institutions elsewhere might be needed. This is particularly true for universal banks with aspirations beyond retail and the lower and middle corporate market. See also my comments below on investment banking;
•A viable role in investment banking requires "deep pockets" and an international, rather than regional presence. Neither condition is or can be met by the Swedish institutions on their own. True aspirations in that direction can only be met with mergers beyond the Nordic market;
•Narrower strategies (e.g. the "traditional" Citibank strategy: retail, asset management and lower/middle corporate market) might allow for a sustainable role as independent regional player. Focus should be on exploiting relationships and services that are targeted to this
•The previous point also implies that financial institutions should aim at optimally exploiting scope economies. I doubt that this allows for broad universal banking strategies by Nordic players unless they engage in alliances, see issue/item v;
•The previous points imply that only narrower strategies are viable for independent Nordic banks. An exception is possibly asset management. This is an important market and at least one of the Nordic players might be able to capitalize on it. The combination of asset management on a large, possibly international scale and regionally focused banking might be feasible. In this way, some synergies could also be obtained with life insurance activities. That is, life insurance could fit with the relationship orientation of the regional bank and simultaneously add to the asset management pool. An alternative is "alliance model" for asset management activities, see issue/item v;
•My impression is that the main strategic options for Nordic banks involve expansion beyond the Nordic market (e.g. Baltic countries) and alliances for investment banking and/or asset management. For some, real integration of life insurance and (possibly) pension business may add directly to the existing
v. Value of alliances
The concept of alliances has yet to be developed in the context of banking. This is to some extent surprising. Banks did, and still do, engage in correspondent banking, particularly in the context of cross- border payment services. But correspondent banking is losing its importance. Why? With the advent of information technology international payment and settlement systems have become available
Volym D:250 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
(e.g. the emergence of TARGET and settlement systems like Cedel and Euroclear). These developments reduce the need for correspondent banking. More importantly, correspondent banks may have become competitors in the areas they were cooperating in before. For example, some banks seek to gain a competitive edge by offering proprietary cross border payment facilities. This points at an important consideration for the feasibility of correspondent banking, or alliances for that matter. It only works if the interests of the participating institutions are sufficiently aligned.24 But why may alliances become important, particularly, within the context of Nordic banking?
The main reason I see is that institutions that seek to capitalize on their local presence, with benefits rooted in strong relationships, cultural adaptation, etc., may need smooth access to some investment banking and asset management services that are scale intensive and globally, rather than locally oriented. It may well be possible to offer some of these services in an alliance (i.e. "to join forces") and capitalize on
First, for several reasons, cross border mergers may not (yet) be feasible. A focused alliance would create valuable linkages between institutions with immediate synergy benefits (see above), but could also allow the possibly
24Observe that correspondent banks could traditionally not enter each others markets. Interests were therefore more readily aligned.
25The experience of some western banks is that top management gets fully distracted by the investment banking activities and spends disproportionally little time on the often more profitable
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:251 |
|
|
|
the word. Similarly, in the case of asset management, the alliance partners would each maintain their own proprietary access to the customers but join forces in the asset management operations including research and back office activities. This would facilitate the information technology investments that allow the partners to capitalize on scale economies. Maintaining proprietary access by the individual alliance partners preserves
6.4The future
There are powerful forces behind consolidation. I believe that consolidation is only partially driven by
The merger wave will continue and, in my view, become excessive (overshooting). Ultimately, it will lead to a level of consolidation in the industry that will be reversed and lead to downsizing and refocusing. In the consolidation phase, however, larger financial institutions will be "forced" to follow "the herd". Swedish banks have rightfully chosen to expand in the Scandinavian territory. This type of regional expansion is in my view value enhancing. Whether Scandinavian banks will ultimately survive as independent financial institutions is questionable. In my view, alliances are crucial to maintain the viability of regionally focused banks. But even then, once the regional expansion in the Scandinavian market is completed, the surviving institutions become prime targets for the powerful Continental European institutions.
26 I have said little about moral hazard and regulation in light of the consolidation. For one reason there is broad agreement: certifying risk management processes is the primary task of supervision, and the EU has quite wisely allocated this task unambiguously to home country supervisors. This is something still to be addressed in the U.S. observing the multiplicity of regulators. The consolidation, and broadening of scope now also observed in the U.S. (e.g. Travelers and Citicorp), amplifies the importance of this issue.
Volym D:252 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
References
Allen, F., (1993), ”Stock Markets and Resource Allocation”, in Capital Markets and Financial Intermediation, C. Mayer and X. Vives, eds., Cambridge University Press.
Allen, F. and D. Gale, (1995), ”A Welfare Comparison of the German and US Financial Systems”, European Economic Review, 39,
Berger, A.N., A.K. Kashyap and J.M. Scalise, (1995), ”The Transformation of the US Banking Industry: What a Long, Strange Trip It's Been”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2,
Berger, A.N., (1997), ”The Efficiency Effects of Bank Mergers and Acquisition: A Preliminary Look at the 1990s Data, forthcoming”, in Bank Mergers and Acquisitions, Yakov Amihud and Geoffrey Miller, eds, Klumer Academic, Boston, MA.
Berger, A.N., R.S. Demsetz and P.E. Strahan, (1999), ”The Consolidation of the Financial Services Industry: Causes, Consequences and Implications for the Future”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 23,
Berger, A.N., W.C. Hunter, and S.G. Timme, (1993), ”The Efficiency of Financial Institutions: A Review and Preview of Research Past, Present and Future”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 17 (special issue on The Efficiency of Financial Institutions),
Berger, P.G. and E. Ofek, (1995), ”Diversification’s Effect on Firm Value”, Journal of Financial Economics, 37,
Berglöf, E. and E.L. von Thadden, (1994),
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109,
Berlin, M., (1996), ”For Better and for Worse: Three Lending Relationships”, Business Review Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, December,
Bhattacharaya, S. and G. Chiesa, (1995), ”Proprietary Information, Financial Intermediation, and Research Incentives”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, 4, pp.
Boot, A.W.A., S.I. Greenbaum and A.V. Thakor, (1993), ”Reputation and Discretion in Financial Contracting”, American Economic Review, 83,
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:253 |
|
|
|
Boot, A.W.A. and S.I. Greenbaum, (1995), ”The Future of Banking: What Should Corporate America Expect?”, Business Week Executive Briefing, 8.
Boot, A.W.A. and J. Macey, (1998), “Objectivity, Proximity and Adaptability in Corporate Governance”, working paper, University of Amsterdam.
Boot, A.W.A., T. Milbourn and A.V. Thakor, (1999), ”Evolution of Organizational Scale and Scope: Does It Ever Pay to Get Bigger and Less Focused?”, working paper, University of Amsterdam.
Boot, A.W.A. and A. V. Thakor, (1997), ”Financial System Architecture”, Review of Financial Studies, 10,
Boot, A.W.A. and A.V. Thakor, (1999), ”Can Relationship Banking Survive Competition?”, working paper, University of Amsterdam.
Boot, A.W.A., A.V. Thakor and G. Udell, (1991), ”Credible Commitments, Contract Enforcement Problems and Banks: Intermediation as Credibility Assurance”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 15,
Boyd, J.H. and M. Gertler, (1994), ”Are Banks Dead, or Are the Reports Greatly Exaggerated?”, working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
Calomiris, C.W. and J. Karceski, (1998), “Is the Bank Merger Wave of the 90’s Efficient? Lessons from nine Case Studies”, working paper, Columbia University.
Canals, J., (1994), “Competitive Strategies in European Banking”, Clarendo Press, Oxford.
Chan, Y., S.I. Greenbaum and A.V. Thakor, (1986), ”Information Reusability, Competition and Bank Asset Quality”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 10,
Clark, J.A., (1996), ”Ec onomic Cost, Scale Efficiency, and Competitive Viability in Banking”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 28,
Comment, R. and G.A. Jarrell, (1995), Corporate Focus and Stock Returns, Journal of Financial Economics, 37,
Cornett, M.M. and H. Tehranian, (1992), ”Changes in Corporate Performance Associated with Bank Acquisition”, Journal of Financial Economics, 31,
Courtney, H., J. Kirkland and P. Viguerie, (1997), ”Strategy under Uncertainty”, Harvard Business Review,
Dewatripont, M. and E. Maskin, (1995), ”Credit and Efficiency in Centralized and Decentralized Economies”, Review of Economic Studies, 62,
Volym D:254 Supplement 27 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Dewatripont, M. and J. Tirole, (1995), The Prudential Regulation of Banks, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachussets.
Diamond, D., (1984), ”Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring”, Review of Economic Studies, 51,
Diamond, D., (1993), ”Seniority and Maturity of Debt Contracts”,
Journal of Financial Economics, 33,
Flannery, M., (1999), ”Comment on Milbourn, Boot and Thakor”,
Journal of Banking and Finance, 23,
Gorton, G. and J. Kahn, (1993), ”The Design of Bank Loan Contracts, Collateral, and Renegotiation”, NBER working paper 4273.
Gorton, G. and G. Pennacchi, (1995), ”Banks and Loan Sales: Marketing Nonmarketable Assets”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 35,
Greenbaum, S.I. and A.V. Thakor, (1995), Contemporary Financial Intermediation, Dryden Press.
Grossman, S.J. and O. Hart, (1986), ”The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and lateral Integration”, Journal of Political Economy,
Hamel, G. and C.K. Prahalad, (1990), ”The Core Competence of the Corporation”, Harvard Business Review,
Hellwig, M., (1991), ”Banking, Financial Intermediation and Corporate Finance”, in European Financial Integration, A. Giovanni and C. Mayer, eds., Cambridge University Press.
Houston, J. and C. James, (1995), Bank Information Monopolies and the Mix of Private and Public Debt Claims, working paper, University of Florida.
James, C., (1987), ”Some Evidence on the Uniqueness of Bank Loans”,
Journal of Financial Economics, 19,
John, K. and E. Ofek, (1995), ”Asset Sales and Increase in Focus”,
Journal of Financial Economics, 37,
Kroszner, R.S. and R. Rajan, (1994), ”Is the
Kulatilaka, N. and E. Perotti, (1998), ”Strategic Growth Options”,
Management Science, 44 (8),
Lummer, S. and J. McConnell, (1989), ”Further Evidence on the Bank Lending Process and the Reaction of the Capital Market to Bank Loan Agreements”, Journal of Financial Economics, 25,
Mayer, C., (1988), ”New Issues in Corporate Finance”, European Economic Review, 32,
SOU 2000:11 |
Consolidation and Strategic Positioning… |
Volym D:255 |
|
|
|
Merton, R.C., (1993), ”Operation and Regulation in Financial Intermediation: A Functional Perspective”, in Operation and Regulation of Financial Markets, P. Englund, ed., Economic Council.
Mester, L.J., (1992), ”Traditional and Nontraditional Banking: An
Mitchell, K. and N.M. Onvural, (1996), ”Ec onomies of Scale and Scope at Large Commercial Banks: Evidence from the Fourier Flexible Functional Form”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 28,
Petersen, M. and R. Rajan, (1994), ”The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data”, Journal of Finance, 49,
Petersen, M. and R. Rajan, (1995), ”The Effect of Credit Market Competition on Lending Relationships”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110,
Puri, M., (1996), ”Commercial Banks in Investment Banking: conflict of Interest or Certification Role?”, Journal of Financial Economics, 40,
Rajan, R., (1992), ”Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice Between Informed and Arm's Length Debt”, Journal of Finance, 47,
Sharpe, S., (1990), ”Asymmetric Information, Bank Lending, and Implicit Contracts: A Stylized Model of Customer Relationships”,
Journal of Finance, 45,
Schmeits, A., (1997), Discretion in Bank Contracts and the Firm's Funding Source Choice between Bank and Financial Market Financing, working paper, Washington University.
Shaffer, S. and E. David, (1991), Economies of Superscale in Commercial Banking, Applied Economics, 23,
Simon, H.C., (1936), Rules versus Authorities in Monetary Policy,
Journal of Political Economy, 44,
SOU 2000:11 |
Volym D:257 |
|
|
Swedish Banking Efficiency and
Productivity in an International Perspective
by
Lennart Hjalmarsson,*
Irene Andersson and
Aziz Mlima
Supplement number 28 to the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
Views, suggestions, and opinions expressed in this study represent the personal views of the authors and not necessarily those of the Government Inquiry on the International Competitiveness of the Swedish Financial Sector.
September, 1999
* Professor i Nationalekonomi vid Handelshögskolan, Göteborgs Universitet. Hjalmarsson forskar inom områdena produktivitet och effektivitet samt energiekonomi och avreglering av marknader. Department of Economics, Göteborg University, P.O.Box 640,
Volym D:258 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Table of Contents
Kort sammanfattning (in Swedish) ..................................................... |
259 |
|
Summary............................................................................................. |
262 |
|
Abstract .............................................................................................. |
264 |
|
1 |
Introduction ............................................................................... |
265 |
2 |
Measurement of efficiency and productivity change.................. |
268 |
2.1 |
Efficiency .............................................................................. |
268 |
2.2 |
Productivity........................................................................... |
272 |
2.3 |
Interpretation of efficiency scores and productivity change...... |
276 |
3 |
Empirical studies........................................................................ |
278 |
3.1 |
Swedish branch office productivity change ............................. |
278 |
3.2Swedish banking efficiency and productivity change 1984-
|
1995...................................................................................... |
283 |
3.3 |
The efficiency of Swedish banking in 1996............................. |
289 |
3.4 |
Banking productivity in a Scandinavian comparison ............... |
294 |
3.5 |
The efficiency of Swedish banks in a European comparison.... |
297 |
References........................................................................................... |
303 |
|
Appendix 1.......................................................................................... |
307 |
|
Appendix 2.......................................................................................... |
310 |
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:259 |
|
|
|
Sammanfattning (in Swedish)
Syftet med denna rapport är att analysera den relativa effektiviteten och produktivitetsutvecklingen inom svensk bankverksamhet. Rapporten inehåller dels en redovisning av ett antal tidigare studier av svensk bankverksamhet, dels vissa nya resultat. På metodsidan utnyttjas olika typer av frontfunktionsanalys, speciellt s.k. stokastiska frontfunktioner samt DEA (Data Envelopment Analysis).
Det stora problemet vid mätning av banksektorns produktivitet är hur produktionen ska definieras och mätas. Utgör inlåningskonton input eller output i bankverksamheten? Mäts banktjänster bäst genom antalet konton och transaktioner eller värdet på dessa? Är hanterandet av konton verkligen den mest betydelsefulla prestationen i
Vid analys av bankers produktion är det två huvudansatser som dominerar i litteraturen med avseende på vilka aspekter som studeras:
•produktionsansats (tjänste- eller förädlingsvärdeansats)
•förmedlingsansats (tillgångsansats)
I produktionsansatsen betraktas banker som producenter av inlåning, utlåning och andra tjänster med hjälp av arbetskraft och kapital. I denna ansats utgör antalet inlåningskonton, antal utestående lån, antal valutatransaktioner etc. outputvariabler. I förmedlingsansatsen betraktas banker som hopsamlare av kapital som sedan omvandlas och förmedlas till lån och andra tillgångar. Volymen i kronor på inlåningskonton och utlåning utgör här output och rörelsekostnader och räntor input i produktionsprocessen. Någon exakt klar gräns mellan de två ansatserna existerar dock inte, utan valet av variabler bestäms nog oftare av tillgängligheten snarare än av ansatsen.
En viktig fråga är hur skillnader i effektivitet mellan produk- tionsenheter ska tolkas. Det är då viktigt att notera att effektivitet som det här definierats är ett mått på avståndet från en enhet till en best- practice front och inte ett mått på någon ”högre form” av effektivitet. Det är också viktigt att notera att vi här endast beaktar resursinsats och produktion i mer eller mindre fysiska termer. Effekter av varierande produktpriser eller faktorpriser, lönsamhet eller avkastning ligger utanför analysen. Med vissa reservationer kan vi säga att en effektivitetsanalys
Volym D:260 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
kan ge en indikation på enheternas relativa konkurrenskraft på en konkurrensutsatt marknad. Detta innebär att inom starkt reglerade sektorer eller sektorer med svag konkurrens kan korrelationen mellan effektivitet och lönsamhet vara mycket svag. Goda finansiella nyckeltal kan lika gärna vara ett uttryck för
Rapportens huvudresultat kan sammanfattas på följande sätt:
•Det existerar ingen generell samsyn i litteraturen när det gäller definitionen av vad som ska klassificeras som producerade tjänster i bankverksamhet och vad som är att betrakta som insatsfaktorer. Det finns en stor variation mellan olika studier. Även inom de två dominerande ansatserna, produktionsansatsen och förmedlingsan- satsen finns det en betydande variation i val av tjänsteproduk- tionsvariabler och insatsfaktorsvariabler. Eftersom de empiriska resultaten inte tycks vara speciellt robusta när det gäller val av variabler på output- och inputsidan utgör naturligtvis detta ett problem vid tolkningen av de empiriska resultaten och vid jämförelser mellan olika undersökningar.
•Ett generellt resultat när det gäller bankeffektivitet och produk- tivitetsförändringar är att resultaten tycks vara mycket känsliga för variationer i servicevolymerna, dvs.
•Effektivitetsanalysen av de svenska bankerna 1996 illustrerar resultatens känslighet med avseende på valet av variabler. Å ena sidan visar sig valet mellan arbetskraftskostnader och arbetstimmar ha endast obetydlig effekt på effektivitetsfördelningen. Å andra sidan visar sig resultaten vara mycket känsliga för inlemmandet eller utelämnandet av nettoprovisioner som en tjänstevariabel. Medan resultaten för de kommersiella bankerna inte påverkas nämnvärt har denna variabel mycket stor effekt på ett antal sparbankers effektivitetsmått.
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:261 |
|
|
|
•I ett skandinaviskt perspektiv var den svenska banksektorn 1990 betydligt mera produktiv än såväl den finska som den norska och danska banksektorn. Denna slutsats gäller också för de största bankerna. Det stora gapet mellan svensk och finsk genomsnitts- produktivitet beror i huvudsak på effektivitetskomponenten, även om Sverige också hade ett teknologiskt försteg.
•Vid en jämförelse mellan ett stort antal europeiska affärsbanker visar sig den genomsnittliga effektivitetsnivån för de svenska affärsbankerna ligga på andra plats från botten, både i en två- faktormodell och i en arbetseffektivitetsmodell. Det är då viktigt att här komma ihåg att analysen är begränsad endast till ett antal affärsbanker i varje land samt till ett fåtal variabler.
•I allmänhet visar det sig vara mycket stor variation i effektivitet mellan olika banker både inom och mellan länder. Jämfört med många andra branscher kan man också à priori förvänta sig en lägre effektivitet och en större spridning i effektivitet i banksektorn och ett större avstånd mellan de mest effektiva och de minst effektiva bankerna. En viktig orsak till detta är det relativt låga konkurrens- trycket i banksektorn i kombination med en blandning av banker med olika typer av ägare och målsättningar, affärsbanker, kooperativa banker och stiftelser utan vinstsyfte, börsnoterade och icke börsnoterade företag. Närliggande orsaker är också den reglerings- struktur som bankerna möter i olika länder och som ytterligare kan öka avståndet mellan de mest effektiva och minst effektiva enheterna.
•Vid en bedömning av den svenska banksektorns internationella konkurrenskraft kan konstateras att samtliga länder uppvisar en stor spridning mellan de mest effektiva och de minst effektiva bankerna. Å andra sidan tyder resultaten på att den svenska banksektorns genomsnittsproduktivitet är relativt låg jämfört med övriga EU- länders. I ett nordiskt perspektiv tycks dock den svenska bank- sektorns produktivitet klart överstiga såväl den finska som den norska och i vissa fall även den danska.
Volym D:262 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Summary
In this report we have briefly surveyed and to some extent extended a couple of empirical studies on Swedish banking efficiency and productivity change on the basis of frontier production function methods. The results may be summarised in the following way:
•In the literature, there is no general agreement on the definition of outputs and inputs in banking, and there is a lot of variation between different studies. Even within each of the two dominant approaches, the production approach (or service provision or value added approach) and the intermediation approach (or asset approach), there is substantial variation Moreover, the empirical results do not seem very robust, but rather depend upon the definition of outputs and inputs – although rather few studies have dealt with this issue.
•In general, banking efficiency and productivity change seem to be very sensitive to fluctuations in output variables, i.e., in capacity utilisation. This is most evident in the case of productivity change at branch offices, which shows high variation between years, strongly correlated with output variation. This is also evident in the years after the banking crisis, when technical change at the frontier turns into regress, from 1992 onwards. As a response to a banking crisis, this may seem counter intuitive. However, it turns out that the result, to a large extent, is driven by the development of output. A major reason for the banking crisis was the dramatic increase in the real rate of interest, causing large changes in household and company portfolios, with extensive repayment of loans and less demand for new loans. While deposits decreased somewhat, loans and guarantees decreased substantially, and it was obviously not possible to adjust labour use at the same rate.
•The efficiency analysis of Swedish banks in 1996 illustrates the sensitivity of the results with respect to choice of variables. On the one hand, the choice between labour costs and labour hours has only minor impact on the efficiency distribution. On the other hand, the results are very sensitive to the inclusion or exclusion of net provisions as an output variable. While the results are robust for the commercial banks – which are all (with one exception) fully efficient, the deviation between models is striking for some savings banks.
•In a Scandinavian comparison, the Swedish banking sector in 1990 was much more productive than the Finnish, Norwegian, and Danish
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:263 |
|
|
|
banking sectors. This conclusion also holds for the largest banks. The large gap between Swedish and Finnish average productivity is mainly due to the efficiency component, although Sweden also has a technology advantage.
•In a European comparison, Swedish
•In general, there is large variation in efficiency between banks both within each country analysed and across countries. In comparison with many other industries, one should also expect lower mean efficiency and a larger dispersion in efficiency scores, i.e., between best practice and worst practice in the banking industry. The main reason for this is the rather low competitive pressure in the banking industry in combination with a mixture of banks with different types of ownership and objectives, commercial banks, cooperative banks and
•Concerning the international competitiveness of Swedish banking, we thus observe a large variation between best practice and worst practice banks in all countries and across countries. In a European comparison the results suggest the average productivity of Swedish banks to be rather low, while in a Scandinavian comparison, we get the opposite conclusion.
Volym D:264 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Abstract
The purpose of this report is to analyse relative efficiency and productivity growth in the Swedish banking sector. We will survey some previous results for the Swedish banking industry, in addition to presenting some new results. One analysis focuses on productivity change at
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:265 |
|
|
|
1 Introduction
The purpose of this report is to analyze relative efficiency and productivity growth in the Swedish banking sector. In recent years, relative efficiency and productivity change in banking have been the focus of a lively debate, though there is still a lack of clarity as to its actual development. The banking sector has also received considerable attention in international studies. Traditionally, the areas of main interest have been analyses of economies of scale and economies of scope, though more recently a number of efficiency and productivity studies have been undertaken. In the aftermath of liberalisation, restructuring, and deregulation of financial markets around the world, there is a recent boom, in activities directed to evaluating the performance of financial institutions. In a recent paper, Berger and Humphrey (1997) survey and contrast the results of 130
A major problem related to the measurement of banking sector productivity is how to define, let alone measure, the sector's output. Triplett (1992), pointed out that progress in measurement of banking has been inhibited by two major unresolved but related questions: (1) What are the outputs? (2) What are the inputs? For instance, are deposit accounts inputs or outputs in its activity? This ambiguity of inputs and outputs was also highlighted by Wykoff (1992): ”When deposits are outputs, why are they so cheap? When they are inputs, why do people provide them to banks?” Are bank services best measured by the number of accounts held and transactions executed, or should the value of transactions be used instead? Is the administration of these accounts really the most important aspect of banking? Is not the bank's role as intermediary between savers and investors the most important from the economic point of view? How would this be measured? For a thorough theoretical and conceptual discussion of these issues, see Berger and Humphrey (1992), Fixler and Zieschang (1992) and Colwell and Davis (1992).
Volym D:266 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Even in 'practical' work, there is an intense discussion relating to the measurement and valuation of a bank's output. Valuing bank production in national accounts has always been controversial. Given the guidelines used today, the banking and financial sector has only a weak contribution (positive or negative) to the growth of GDP. In relation to the revised international system of national accounts (SNA), a number of alternatives regarding the treatment of banking and financial activities have been suggested. In most cases, the suggestions would imply a marked increase in the sector's contribution to GDP.
Humphrey (1984) divided studies of banks' production into two distinct strands, depending on the nature of the analytical approach:
•the production approach, also called the service provision or value added approach
•the intermediation approach, also called the asset approach
In the production approach, banks provide services to customers by handling their financial transactions, keeping customers deposits, issuing loans, cashing cheques, etc. Here the number of deposit accounts, outstanding loans, foreign exchange transactions, etc., are the output variables, with labour and capital as inputs
In the intermediation approach, banks are performing the two major roles of mobilising and distributing resources efficiently, in order to smooth investment activities in the economy. In this approach, the inputs are labour, materials, and deposits, while outputs are loans and other income generating activities to the banks, see e.g. Mester (1997). In some studies, the monetary volume of the deposit accounts and the loans comprise the output, while the costs of operation and the interest due are the inputs in the production process. This approach has two major sub- groups: (a) the profit approach, and (b) the risk management approach.
In the profit approach, the bank manager’s target is to optimise the use of resources to maximise the bank’s profit function. In this approach, the bank manager cares for all types of costs in the banks and the output is the net income generated after incurring certain costs in the production process.
In the risk management approach, banks transform assets, on the basis of evaluation of the risks attached to various forms of asset. In risk management, banks take some risks to produce acceptable returns. A bank's performance will affect its valuation in the market, its ability to acquire other banks or to be acquired at a good price, and its ability to be funded through deposits or financial markets.
In both the production approach and the intermediation approach, the definition of output is strictly limited to production within banking. To what extent banks actually fulfill their role as producers of financial
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:267 |
|
|
|
services lies beyond the scope of this analytical framework. This limitation is acceptable if the intention, as here, is to estimate productivity growth separately for different
This report contains several pieces of empirical research related to Swedish banks. For a start, we will survey (and slightly develop) a few studies of efficiency and productivity change in Swedish banking. Then we will focus on the efficiency and productivity of Swedish banking in international comparisons.
In one part of this report the production approach is used to review how one of the largest Swedish commercial banks use labour and capital to produce certain
In other parts of this report, the intermediation approach is used. In these cases the sample is collected from banks´ annual reports. Here micro units are entire banks, with one or more offices.
Because this report focuses on productive efficiency and productivity change, we use various kinds of frontier models, described in Section 2. The empirical results are presented in Section 3.
1 Other studies with a similar approach are Sherman and Gold (1985), Tulkens (1993) and Vassiloglou and Giokas (1990). In these studies, the analysis is based on the spread of efficiency between bank offices for a particular year.
Volym D:268 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
2Measurement of efficiency and productivity change
2.1Efficiency
Measurement of efficiency in the sense of evaluating the performance of production units against a benchmark or yardstick, under the heading of frontier analysis, is becoming increasingly widespread. Frontier analysis provides a ranking of production units in terms of their efficiency, and it also attributes a numerical efficiency value to each production unit. This makes it possible to identify best practice and worst practice in a sector, and the measurement of efficiency has in fact been the main motivation for the intensive study of frontier functions.
Thus, for a variety of reasons, in recent years frontier analysis has become a very attractive and rather sophisticated way to benchmark the relative performance of production units. First, the notion of a frontier is consistent with the underlying economic theory of optimising behavior. Second, deviations from a frontier have a natural interpretation as a measure of the efficiency with which economic units pursue their technical or behavioral objectives. Finally, information about the structure of the frontier, and about the relative efficiency of economic units has many policy applications. One example is the setting of productivity targets in
To serve as a meaningful benchmark, the frontier should represent
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:269 |
|
|
|
•Functional form of the frontier function, especially the choice between a parametric form and a
•Stochastic properties, especially the choice between a deterministic and a stochastic approach.
•Distribution assumed for the inefficiency scores (usually
In this report we are only concerned with production frontiers; i.e., our data consists of output and input variables. In measuring efficiency we adopt the system introduced by Forsund and Hjalmarsson (1974), a generalisation of Farrell’s measures to a
A measure of efficiency is the distance between an inefficient unit and the frontier, which can be measured in several ways. Here we focus on
2 The basic idea of measuring efficiency on the basis of frontiers goes back to Farrell (1957), who introduced a deterministic
Volym D:270 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
have been produced, with observed input and frontier technology. Efficient frontier units have a value of 1, inefficient ones less than 1.
Figure 1. An illustration of efficiency measures
VRS efficiency measures for any unit at D are:
E1 |
= |
HJ/HD |
= |
|
E2 |
= |
ND/NL |
= |
|
The CRS efficiency measure is |
||||
E |
= |
HI/HD |
= ND/NG = technical efficiency |
Unit D will be both
There are several summary measures of the efficiency of the entire sector, so called structural efficiency measures. One such measure is the mean of efficiency scores, or a
As regards determination of the frontier, two approaches dominate today:
•SFA = Stochastic frontier analysis – the dominant econometric approach
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:271 |
|
|
|
•DEA = Data envelopment analysis – the dominant programming approach
SFA uses a parametric representation of technology, along with a two- part composed error term. One part of the composed error term represents statistical noise, and is assumed to follow a normal distribution. The other part represents technical inefficiency, and is usually assumed to follow a skewed distribution such as a half normal, truncated normal, exponential, or gamma distribution. One problem with
One weakness with SFA is that if the functional form is mis- specified, measured efficiency may be confounded with specification errors. Another weakness of this approach is its limited usefulness in the case of multiple output – multiple input production when input price data is not available. A third weakness is its sensitivity to heteroscedasticity; i.e., the impact on the estimated efficiency scores when firms in a
The major competing frontier approach is the very popular non- parametric data envelopment analysis (DEA) approach. This approach imposes less structure on the frontier, which is formed as the piecewise linear combination of
•It is sensitive to outliers; i.e., units that are extreme in some sense (e.g. small offices run by workaholics)
Volym D:272 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
•An increase in the number of outputs or inputs leads to an increase in efficiency scores. In small samples with many variables almost all units may be on the frontier.
•An increase in the number of production units yields a decrease in efficiency scores. Thus, a comparison of efficiency levels across industries requires adjustment for sample size; see Zhang and Bartels (1998).
It is not possible to determine which of the two major approaches dominates the other, since the true level of efficiency is unknown. Because in DEA all deviations from the frontier are interpreted as inefficiency, the SFA approach normally yields higher efficiency levels than DEA.
A more technical description of the two approaches is given in Appendix 1, which presents the mathematical formulation of the models applied in this report.
2.2Productivity
The general definition of total factor productivity, TFP, is the ratio between an output index and an input index. This definition raises the question how outputs and inputs should be aggregated in the respective indexes. If a production function is used as an aggregator, the weights will be the marginal elasticities on both the output and the input side. This is the conventional aggregation approach.
Another type of aggregation is the proportional shrinking of an input vector and proportional expansion of an output vector. This is the aggregation performed in the
We are often not so much interested in TFP per se, but in comparisons of TFP over time or across regions. Thus, TFP comparisons are binary comparisons between two observations in time or in space, while as we saw above, efficiency is measured against a common reference technology – the frontier.
For a parametric production function, the change in TFP over time is usually measured by the shift in production possibilities, which is the same as technical change. This is the
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:273 |
|
|
|
With DEA however, which is
The MTP index is only based on quantity variables, but nevertheless knowledge about at least one technology is required. This index and its parts can be expressed completely in terms of Farrell efficiency measures, so the need for technology information boils down to being able to calculate these measures. Thus, MTP fits very well as a complement to DEA3.
Thus, the Malmquist productivity index offers an alternative way to measure productivity at a sectoral level. A graphical presentation of the total Malmquist productivity index is provided in Figure 2. Here we illustrate the construction of the
3 Originally, within a consumer theory context, Malmquist (1953) introduced the notion of proportional scaling of quantities observed in year t2 to allow a consumer the same utility level as in year t1. The proportional scaling factor was interpreted as a quantity index. Caves et al (1982) developed the Malmquist idea to a productivity index proper. However, the link to DEA was first developed by Färe et al (1994), (originally a working paper in 1989). They showed the relative ease with which the index could be calculated in the case of piecewise linear frontiers and since then there has been a rapidly increasing number of empirical applications. The additional attraction added by Färe et al (1994) was to maintain inefficient operations and decomposing productivity change into efficiency improvement and production frontier shift in the general case of multiple outputs and inputs, thus generalising the parametric single output approach in Nishimizu and Page (1982).
Volym D:274 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Figure 2. Construction of the Malmquist total productivity index, MTP
P is a production unit observed for two years, t and t+1. Between these time points the frontier function has shifted from ft to ft+1. In year t, technical efficiency for Pt measured against ft is
Et,t = OC/OD
where the first index denotes the frontier year, and the second index denots the observation. Measured against ft+1 technical efficiency for pt is
Et+1,t = OA/OD
Correspondingly, technical efficiency for Pt+1 relative to ft+1 is
Et+1,t+1 = OB/OE
and measured against ft it is
Et,t+1 = OF/OE
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:275 |
|
|
|
The Malmquist
M t = Et,t+1
Et,t
The Malmquist
M t+1 = Et+1,t+1
Et+1,t
M >1 means productivity improvement, while M<1 means productivity decline.
The Malmquist index can be decomposed into two components, MC and MFi.
MC is the change in efficiency relative to the frontier: i.e.,a catching up productivity index:
OB
MC = OE = Et+1,t+1
OC Et,t
OD
MF is the change in distance to the frontier; i.e., a productivity index:
MFi = |
Et, j |
, i, j = t,t +1 i j |
|
Et+1, j |
|||
|
|
||
and |
|
A total productivity index, can then be defined as Mi = MC x MFi:
For a fully efficient observation both years, MC = 1. The index is then a pure frontier – distance measure.
In general, the choice of reference technology is important for the empirical result. If there is no strong reason to choose a certain base, an alternative originally suggested in Färe et al (1994), is to take the geometric mean of Mt and Mt+1,
MG = [Mt Mt+1]1/2
Volym D:276 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
In calculating the efficiency measures in Section 3.2 on which the subsequent Malmquist index is based, we have confined ourselves to the model with constant returns to scale. With regard to comparisons over time, this is fully plausible, since differences in
2.3Interpretation of efficiency scores and productivity change
There are several reasons to be careful with interpretation of the empirical results of efficiency and productivity studies. For a start, what has come to be called efficiency measures is nothing but measures of distances from production units to a frontier. Especially in DEA with variable returns to scale, the frontier envelops closely around the data set. This means that a production unit may be at the frontier not because it is a well performing unit, but just because it lacks competition in that segment of the frontier. Typically, a closer look at a small frontier unit reveals it to be a rather poorly performing unit in terms of partial productivities. But given its size, it is still a frontier unit with efficiency score of 1. One should therefore check which units are
As discussed above, because of the inherent properties of the frontier techniques applied here, one should expect SFA to give higher mean efficiency, a smaller dispersion in a
In comparison with many other industries, one should also expect a lower degree of mean efficiency and a larger dispersion in efficiency
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:277 |
|
|
|
scores; i.e., between best practice and worst practice in the banking industry. The main reason for this is the rather low competitive pressure in the banking industry in combination with a mixture of banks with different types of ownership and objectives, commercial banks, cooperative banks, and
The rate of productivity change may also influence the distance between best practice and worst practice. During periods of rapid technical progress at the frontier, many production units may have difficult catching up and lag behind for some time, causing a decrease in mean efficiency. On the other hand, during periods of slow technical progress at the frontier, one would expect units below the frontier to catch up, causing an increase in mean efficiency.
Concerning interpretation of productivity change measures, one should bear in mind that, in general, productivity measures are rather
Volym D:278 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
3 Empirical studies
3.1Swedish branch office productivity change
3.1.1The data
Analyses of productivity or efficiency at the branch office level are very rare; one of the few studies is Hjalmarsson et al (1991). This study covers the period 1983 to 1989 for the branch offices of one of the biggest Swedish commercial banks. The main reson for including this somewhat old study here is to show the large variation in productivity change between years at the bank office level and the large variation in efficiency among offices within a single bank. Data was derived from a computerised statistical system for
•Deposits; this refers to activities directed to the acquisition of savings and to related services.
•Cashing; this refers to
•Loans; this refers to activities related to the granting of credit.
•Trusteeship (Notariat); this refers only to the administration of assets which is related to the branch offices' depots. In the big cities, there are central notary (trust) departments that administer assets for a large number of customers. These departments are not included in the study.
•Foreign Related; this includes, foreign currency and traveller’s cheques as well as payments to abroad undertaken directly by the office. The bulk of foreign transactions are executed at centrally
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:279 |
|
|
|
based and specialised departments using computers. These are left out of the analysis.
•Fund; this refers to that portion of the securities trade that is undertaken at the offices (delivery, swaps, payments etc.). Even here there exist
•Lawyer; this is a collective expenditure item used for those few offices which have their own bank lawyer.
•The following inputs are included:
•Time worked:
•Information technology, IT: costs for administrative data processing, measured in kSEK.
•Office space: measured in square meters.
Due to a statistical reorganisation between 1987 and 1988, these two years are not fully comparable. We thus divide the sample period into two parts:
We also note the following:
•1984 and 1985 were years of low production across the board, the sharp decline having set in during 1983. This decline was reversed into an increase for
•Costs for information technology increased for all years.
•Office space, not unexpectedly, remained for the most part constant.
3.1.2Empirical results
Average productivity growth
Table 1a shows productivity growth for a constructed average office (using the arithmetic mean), while mean (unweighted) productivity growth for the offices is presented in Table 1b.
Volym D:280 |
Supplement 28 |
|
SOU 2000:11 |
||
|
|
|
|
||
Table 1a. Productivity changes for the average office, per cent |
|
|
|||
|
|
MTP |
MC |
MF |
|
1983/84 |
|
||||
1984/85 |
1 |
|
|||
1985/86 |
34 |
0 |
34 |
|
|
1986/87 |
1 |
5 |
|
||
|
1988/89 |
14 |
2 |
12 |
|
MTP is the Malmquist total productivity index, MC the
Table 1b. Productivity changes for the office mean, per cent
|
MTP |
MC |
MF |
1983/84 |
11 |
||
1984/85 |
|||
1985/86 |
32 |
37 |
|
1986/87 |
6 |
4 |
2 |
1988/89 |
13 |
4 |
8 |
The MTP value of
Though there was a reduction in labour input from 1983 to 1985, computer input increased, while
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:281 |
|
|
|
labour is the only input, but where the outputs are the same as in the main model.
Table 2. Labour productivity change for the office mean, per cent
|
MTP |
MC |
MF |
1983/84 |
15 |
||
1984/85 |
|||
1985/86 |
29 |
34 |
|
1986/87 |
7 |
0 |
7 |
1988/89 |
16 |
16 |
The pattern is the same as that for total productivity although the labour productivity decline for 1983/84 was smaller. Moreover, labour productivity rose markedly in 1986/87, while MTP was almost constant.
Development of the individual offices
We have differentiated the individual offices with respect to their rate of productivity growth. Table 3 presents the number of offices with total productivity growth exceeding 5 per cent per year, the number from 5 to 2 per cent per year, those from 0 to 2 per cent per year, and the number of offices with negative productivity change.
The drastic change in productivity growth between the periods 1983/85 and 1985/89 is indisputable. While only a few offices had some productivity growth during 1983/85, the reverse is true for the second
Table 3. Number of offices in different ranges of productivity change
1983/84 |
1984/85 |
1985/86 |
1986/87 |
1988/89 |
|
MTP > 5 % |
2 |
14 |
123 |
40 |
89 |
5 % > MTP > 2 % |
0 |
12 |
3 |
5 |
17 |
2 % > MTP > 0 % |
1 |
8 |
3 |
11 |
6 |
MTP < 0 % |
129 |
100 |
3 |
47 |
21 |
Efficiency
The spread of efficiency between offices together with the average office’s efficiency; i.e., its distance from the
Volym D:282 Supplement 28 |
|
|
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
|||
|
|
|
|
||||||
|
Table 4. Number of offices in different ranges of efficiency and structural |
|
|
||||||
|
efficiency each year |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Efficiency/Year |
1983 |
1984 |
1985 |
1986 |
1987 |
1988 |
1989 |
|
|
E = 1 |
42 |
30 |
51 |
36 |
29 |
36 |
29 |
|
|
1 < E > 0,90 |
23 |
29 |
23 |
26 |
18 |
20 |
34 |
|
|
0,90 < E > 0,80 |
36 |
43 |
32 |
33 |
39 |
32 |
34 |
|
|
0,80 < E > 0,70 |
25 |
24 |
26 |
28 |
22 |
33 |
28 |
|
|
0,70 < E > 0,60 |
5 |
6 |
10 |
8 |
24 |
10 |
7 |
|
|
E < 0,60 |
1 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
1 |
|
|
Structural efficiency |
0.72 |
0.80 |
0.75 |
0.72 |
0.75 |
0.75 |
0.78 |
|
Structural efficiency during the period was within the interval
The shape of the efficiency distribution shows relatively little variation. However, the number of frontier units varies considerably over the years.
3.1.3Conclusions
The results are summarised as follows:
•Total factor productivity increased strongly during
•Labour productivity grew somewhat more than total factor productivity
•Productivity growth was relatively uneven with a decline during
•The distance between the frontier and the average has changed only minimally.
•Productivity growth varies markedly between branch offices.
•The structural efficiency measure suggests a productivity- improvement potential of
•The spread of efficiency varies relatively little over the years.
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:283 |
|
|
|
3.2Swedish banking efficiency and productivity change
In this section we report on a study, Battese et al (1997), investigating efficiency and productivity change in Swedish banks during
3.2.1The data
The data set was obtained from the annual reports of Swedish banks. The data is not from a sample, but the entire population of Swedish banks. The data involved are for the years, 1984 to 1995. During the period some banks ceased to exist and others were established. Some of the changes were due to amalgamations of banks, or to
The data is at the bank level rather than at individual branch level. Hence the large national banks with a large number of branches report only aggregate data. Other small regional banks may involve only one branch, and so the data are for that bank which is identical to a branch. Data for some small banks was deleted from the analysis because the values of one or more of the variables were missing or were clear outliers. This was particularly the case with some banks with only one or two
The variables, public loans, guarantees, and deposits, are regarded as outputs. A key input variable of interest in a study of the efficiency of the banking industry is labour, because it is a significant component in the cost structure of banks. The efficiency of the use of labour in producing the relevant outputs, given the values of the
Volym D:284 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Labour use varied from about 800 to over 20 million employee hours per year. The values of public loans, guarantees, and deposits, also indicate the considerable variation in the size of the banks. The average number of years for which the banks were observed was about 10 years.
3.2.2Empirical results
Efficiency
The individual technical inefficiencies of labour use for the banks range from 0 % to 166 % over the period. Thus, one bank was estimated to be fully technically efficient in labour use in at least one year, whereas another bank was estimated to use 166 % more labour than for a fully efficient bank with the same level of outputs and
Of the 13 banks with inefficiency more than 20 % in the last year they were observed, 10 disappeared from the data set before 1995. Of the three surviving banks, two were savings banks and the other was a recently started international bank with a
Mean technical inefficiencies of labour use for the banks are graphed by year in Figure 3.
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:285 |
|
|
|
Figure 3. Mean technical inefficiency of labour use for Swedish banks, 1984- 1995, per cent
Per cent
16 |
|
|
|
|
|
14 |
|
|
|
|
|
12 |
|
|
|
|
|
10 |
|
|
|
|
|
8 |
|
|
|
|
|
6 |
|
|
|
|
|
4 |
|
|
|
|
|
2 |
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
1984 |
1986 |
1988 |
1990 |
1992 |
1994 |
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
Mean technical inefficiency tended to increase from 1984 to 1991, during the period of rapid expansion when the banks were in vigorous competition for market shares. After the crisis in 1992, mean technical inefficiency decreased slowly. Overall, there was a slight increase in mean technical inefficiency of labour use over the
The results also indicate that the efficiency by the banks tend to:
•be larger for Föreningsbanken, Handelsbanken and Savings banks than for Other Banks;
•be smaller for
•decrease as the number of branches increase;
•increase as the total inventories increase;
Because inventories are measured by book values, they reflect the modernity of these and especially for computer equipment with short depreciation periods. Thus, the
The mean technical inefficiencies of the five types of banks, considered in the study, are given in Table 5. The difference between the two largest commercial banks is striking.
Volym D:286 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
||
|
|
|
|
|
Table 5. Mean technical inefficiency of labour use by bank type, |
|
|
|
Type of Bank Mean |
Technical Inefficiency (%) |
|
|
1: Föreningsbanken (FB) |
5.4 |
|
|
2: Handelsbanken (HB) (Commercial; Particular bank) |
7.3 |
|
|
3: Sparbanker (SB) (Savings; Several banks) |
11.3 |
|
|
4: |
30.4 |
|
|
5: Other Banks (Commercial; A few banks) |
19.2 |
|
While Handelsbanken had an inefficiency level below 10 % for all years,
Among the savings banks, there was substantial variation in inefficiency not reflected in the aggregated figure in Table 5. Most of these banks are local or regional banks operating as
Technical change and efficiency change
The rate of technical change (TC) in labour use is estimated to be negative for all years, but small in absolute values, see Figure 4. This indicates that there was modest technical progress in the frontier labour use during the years of our study. Starting at technical progress of 1.5 % in 1984, the industry continued to have technical progress, but at a decreasing rate, until 1992, when technical progress in labour use was effectively exhausted. Among the bank types, only Handelsbanken experienced technical regress in labour use over the entire period.
Inefficiency (IC) change of labour use over time was positive during
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:287 |
|
|
|
decreased somewhat. The dynamic interplay between changes in the frontier (technical change) and changes in inefficiency is discussed in more detail in Hjalmarsson (1973), Førsund and Hjalmarsson (1974) and Førsund, Hjalmarsson and Summa (1996).
One might have expected a much stronger impact of deregulation and the subsequent banking crisis on the efficiency of labour use in Swedish banks. An important reason why this did not occur might be the rapid return of Swedish banks to profitability which restored their access to capital markets. Most of the
Figure 4. Technical change (TC) and inefficiency change (IC) in labour use by Swedish banks,
Per cent
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
TC |
1.5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
IC |
1 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
84 |
85 |
86 |
87 |
88 |
89 |
90 |
91 |
92 |
93 |
94 |
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
|
|
|
Figure 5 shows the relative movement of outputs, inventories and labour hours over the period, relative to 100 at the branch level in 1984.
Volym D:288 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Figure 5. Development of mean output and mean input
Index 1984=100
300 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Loans |
|
|
|
|
|
Guarantees |
250 |
|
|
|
|
Deposits |
|
|
|
|
|
Hours |
|
|
|
|
|
Inventories |
200 |
|
|
|
|
|
150 |
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
|
|
|
|
|
50 |
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
1984 |
1986 |
1988 |
1990 |
1992 |
1994 |
|
|
|
Year |
|
|
A major reason for the banking crisis in 1992 was the dramatic increase in the real rate of interest causing large changes in household and company portfolios with extensive repayment of old loans and less demand for new loans. Although deposits decreased somewhat in 1992, public loans, guarantees and inventories decreased substantially, and adjustments in the labour use was not at the same rate.
3.2.3Conclusions
Inefficiency of labour use varied considerably for different banks over the period; overall inefficiency was estimated to be about 12 %. This implies that banks, on average, were using about 12 % more labour than if they were fully efficient, given the levels of outputs and
An unexpected pattern emerges concerning the impact of deregulation and the subsequent banking crisis on technical change at the frontier. There was a decrease in technical change at the frontier and an increase in mean technical efficiency. While the development of efficiency seems to be driven by the frontier change, the change in the frontier is to a large extent driven by the development of output. Dramatic increases in the real rate of interest caused large changes in household and company portfolios, with extensive repayment of old, loans and less demand for
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:289 |
|
|
|
new loans. In general, the frontier banks did not manage to adjust the labour use in proportion to the decline in output.
3.3The efficiency of Swedish banking in 1996
In addition to the analysis in the previous section, we have calculated DEA efficiency scores for Swedish banks in 1996. To investigate the sensitivity of the results with respect to the choice of variables, we compare the outcomes of different specifications under variable returns to scale (VRS) and constant returns to scale (CRS).
3.3.1The data
The variables in this data set overlap with the previous one. We use the same basic three output variables, loans, guarantees, and deposits, but now we also add net provisions, i.e., the difference between commissions and other service charges received and the costs related to these. On the input side we use the number of branch offices, inventories, other costs, credit losses, and labour costs, or alternatively, hours worked. Thus, one important part of this section is to investigate the sensitivity of the results with respect to the choice of variables. Not including net provisions might "punish" especially the commercial banks or the larger banks. On the other hand, banks with large net provisions may also have more
Table 6. The difference between the models applied
Variabl |
Net |
Labour |
Labour |
Number |
Number |
e |
provisions |
costs |
hours |
of outputs |
of inputs |
Model 1 |
Yes |
Yes |
|
4 |
5 |
Model 2 |
Yes |
|
Yes |
4 |
5 |
Model 3 |
|
Yes |
|
3 |
5 |
Model 4 |
|
|
Yes |
3 |
5 |
Volym D:290 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
3.3.2Empirical results
All inputs
Empirical results are illustrated in Figures
In general, with so many variables one would expect a rather large number of
Figure 6. Input saving efficiency for Swedish banks, 1996: A comparison between variable and constant returns to scale
Input saving efficiency |
|
1,00 |
|
0,90 |
|
0,80 |
|
0,70 |
|
0,60 |
|
0,50 |
|
0,40 |
|
0,30 |
|
0,20 |
|
0,10 |
Model 1vrs |
Model 1crs |
|
0,00 |
|
|
Units |
Reduction in the number of variables also has a strong impact on the number of frontier units; see Figure 8, where the number of outputs is decreased from 4 to 3, or Figures 10 and 11, with labour as the only input. In the former case the number of frontier units decreased from 31 to 25.
The choice between labour costs and labour hours has only a minor impact on the efficiency distribution; see Figures 7 and 9, in which Models 1 and 2 almost coincide, as do Models 3 and 4. Under VRS, four to six units (all savings banks) which are on the frontier in Model 1 become inefficient in the other models. Under CRS, four to seven banks become inefficient when moving from Model 1 to the other models; all
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:291 |
|
|
|
these are savings banks except Nordbanken which becomes inefficient in Models 2 and 4 (efficiency scores 0.94 and 0.88, respectively), i.e., when labour hours are substituted for labour costs.
On the other hand, there is a substantial difference between Models 1 and 2 on the one hand and Models 3 and 4 on the other; i.e., the results are very sensitive to the inclusion or exclusion of net provisions as an output variable. This is even more clear from Figure 8, which illustrates the difference between Model 1 and Model 3. Mean efficiency decreases from 0.89 in Model 1 to 0.73 in Model 3. All commercial banks (except Östgöta Enskilda Bank) are on the frontier in both models. For three units (Finn, Alingsås and Roslagen savings banks) there is a deviation in efficiency scores exceeding 0.50.
Figure 7. Input saving efficiencyfor Swedish banks, 1996, variable returns to scale
|
1 |
|
|
0,9 |
|
|
0,8 |
|
efficiency |
0,7 |
|
0,6 |
|
|
0,5 |
|
|
saving |
|
|
0,4 |
|
|
Input |
|
|
0,3 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,2 |
Model 1 |
|
Model 2 |
|
|
|
|
|
0,1 |
Model 3 |
|
Model 4 |
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
Units |
Volym D:292 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Figure 8. Efficiency distribution with and without net provisions as an output variable, variable returns to scale
|
1 |
|
|
|
0,9 |
|
|
|
0,8 |
|
|
efficiency |
0,7 |
|
|
0,6 |
|
||
|
|
||
saving |
0,5 |
|
|
0,4 |
|
||
Input |
|
||
0,3 |
Model 1 |
||
|
|||
|
|
||
|
0,2 |
Model 3 |
|
|
0,1 |
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
Units |
Labour use efficiency
When labour is used as the only input, the number of frontier units decreases from 31 to 10 in Model 1 under VRS and from 14 to 3 under CRS; see Figures 10 and 11. Variation between the models is very large.Under VRS mean efficiency decreases from 0.79 in Model 1 to 0.45 in Model 4, and under CRS from 0.67 to 0.27. While all the commercial banks (except Östgöta Enskilda Bank) are on the frontier in Model 1 under VRS, only Handelsbanken and JP Bank are on the frontier in all four models. In CRS only Handelsbanken and JP Bank (along with Alingsås sparbank in Model 1 only) are on the frontier in all models, while
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:293 |
|
|
|
Figure 9. Efficiency distribution for Swedish banks, 1996. Constant returns to
scale |
|
|
|
1 |
|
|
0,9 |
|
|
0,8 |
|
|
0,7 |
|
Efficiency |
0,6 |
|
0,5 |
|
|
0,4 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,3 |
|
|
0,2 |
Model 1 |
|
|
Model 2 |
|
0,1 |
Model 3 |
|
0 |
Model 4 |
|
|
|
|
|
Units |
Figure 10. Labour use efficiency for Swedish banks, 1996. Variable returns to
scale |
|
|
|
1 |
|
|
0,9 |
|
|
0,8 |
|
efficiency |
0,7 |
|
0,6 |
|
|
|
|
|
saving |
0,5 |
|
0,4 |
|
|
Input |
|
|
0,3 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,2 |
Model 1 |
|
Model 2 |
|
|
|
|
|
0,1 |
Model 3 |
|
Model 4 |
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
Units |
Volym D:294 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Figure 11. Labour use efficiency for Swedish banks, 1996. Constant returns to
scale |
|
|
|
1 |
|
|
0,9 |
|
|
0,8 |
Model 1 |
|
Model 2 |
|
|
0,7 |
Model 3 |
|
Model 4 |
|
|
|
|
Efficiency |
0,6 |
|
0,5 |
|
|
0,4 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,3 |
|
|
0,2 |
|
|
0,1 |
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
Units |
3.3.3Conclusions
Efficiency analysis of Swedish banks in 1996 illustrates the sensitivity of the results with respect to choice of variables. On the one hand, the choice between labour costs and labour hours has only a minor impact on the efficiency distribution, but on the other hand, the results are very sensitive to the inclusion or exclusion of net provisions as an output variable. While the results are robust for the commercial banks – which are all (with one exception) fully efficient – the differences between models for some savings banks are quite striking.
3.4Banking productivity in a Scandinavian comparison
Because of low cultural barriers to entry into each other’s markets, the performance of Swedish banking in comparison with its Scandinavian neighbours is of great interest. This issue was analysed in a few studies about 1990, and although there are plans to update these, this has not yet been realised; see Berg et al (1993) and Bukh et al (1995) which will be dealt with here.
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:295 |
|
|
|
3.4.1The data
The data set in Berg et al (1993) consists of observations from 503 Finnish, 150 Norwegian, and 126 Swedish banks. Only a few, quite small, banks in each country have been omitted, due to data collection problems. The data were collected from official bank statistics in Norway and Finland, and from annual reports in Sweden, for the year 1990.
The output variables are deposits loans, and the number of branches.
The input variables are number of hours worked and the book value of machinery and equipment.
To convert monetary values into a common unit, both the official exchange rate and the purchasing- power parity rate as computed by the OECD were used, but it did not matter very much which rate was used.
In Bukh et al (1995) the data set for 1990 was extended to include 182 Danish banks and the variables were extended to include guarantees as an output, and
3.4.2Empirical results
Berg et al (1993) uses the Malmquist productivity index; Sweden is chosen as the technology base for productivity comparisons, due to the superior performance of its largest banks. A common technology base facilitates intercountry comparisons, but the choice of base country will influence the results. Productivity comparisons are shown in Table 7.
Volym D:296 |
Supplement 28 |
|
|
|
|
SOU 2000:11 |
||
|
|
|
||||||
|
Table 7. Intercountry productivity comparisons, 1990, average and largest units |
|||||||
|
in each country |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Malmquist produc- |
Efficiency |
|
Technology component |
|||
|
|
tivity index (MTP) |
component (MC) |
(MF) |
|
|
||
|
Scale |
VRS |
CRS |
VRS |
CRS |
VRS |
CRS |
|
|
Norway/Finland: |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Average |
12 % |
9 % |
7 % |
5 % |
31 % |
|
|
|
Largest |
19 % |
0 % |
47 % |
|
|||
|
Sweden/Finland: |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Average |
63 % |
52 % |
48 % |
39 % |
10 % |
9 % |
|
|
Largest |
35 % |
51 % |
0 % |
43 % |
35 % |
5 % |
|
|
Sweden/Norway: |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Average |
46 % |
40 % |
38 % |
68 % |
5 % |
|
|
|
Largest |
64 % |
27 % |
0 % |
77 % |
64 % |
|
The average Norwegian bank has about 10 % higher productivity than the Finnish average bank, 12 % under VRS, 9 % under CRS. For the largest bank the scale assumption is crucial, with 18 % higher Finnish productivity under VRS, as opposed to 19 % higher Norwegian productivity under CRS.
The Swedish average bank is much more productive than both the Finnish and the Norwegian average bank, 63 % higher than Finnish under VRS, 52 % under CRS, and 40 % and 46 % respectively, higher than Norwegian. The Swedish largest banks are also much more productive.
As discussed earlier the Malmquist productivity index can be decomposed into an efficiency component and a frontier technology component, the latter measuring the distance of the frontier technologies relative to the Swedish
The large gap between Swedish and Finnish average productivity is mainly due to the efficiency component, although Sweden also has a technology advantage. The efficiency component explains even more of the
The extension of the data set to include Danish banks and inclusion of one more output and input variable does not change the previous picture very much; see Table 8.
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:297 |
||||||
|
|
|
||||||
Table 8. Intercountry productivity comparisons, 1990. Malmquist productivity |
||||||||
index, average and largest units in each country |
|
|
|
|
||||
|
|
|
VRS |
|
|
CRS |
|
|
|
|
|
Average unit |
Largest unit |
Average |
Largest unit |
||
|
|
|
|
|
unit |
|
|
|
|
Norway/Finland |
|
4 % |
16 % |
|
2 % |
|
|
|
Denmark/Finland |
|
51 % |
16 % |
32 % |
|
67 % |
|
|
Denmark/Norway |
46 % |
0 % |
40 % |
|
63 % |
|
|
|
Sweden/Finland |
|
64 % |
16 % |
55 % |
|
39 % |
|
|
Sweden/Norway |
|
59 % |
0 % |
64 % |
|
36 % |
|
|
Sweden/Denmark |
9 % |
0 % |
18 % |
|
|
The average Swedish bank still has a higher productivity than the average bank in the other Scandinavian countries, now including Denmark, both under VRS and CRS.
3.4.3Conclusions
In an
3.5The efficiency of Swedish banks in a European comparison
As the final step in this review of empirical studies, we draw on a study by Andersson (1999) on the relative efficiency of a set of large European banks observed in 1996.
3.5.1The data
This analysis is based on a sample of 104 of the largest banks in eight countries, i.e., the Netherlands, Denmark, Belgium, France, Italy, Great
Volym D:298 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Britain, Sweden and Germany. The German, British, Italian and French banking markets constitute the largest markets in Europe, while the remaining four are representing the smaller market places; see Table 9. The complete list of banks is reported in Appendix 2.
Table 9. The distribution of banks
Country |
Number of banks |
Germany |
21 |
Italy |
17 |
UK |
16 |
France |
14 |
Sweden |
11 |
Belgium |
11 |
Denmark |
9 |
Netherlands |
5 |
Most of the countries in the study have a few core banks, which are dominant players in their domestic markets, but their importance is largely balanced by equally important regional banking groups, particularly in Germany, France, and Italy: Table 10 shows two size indicators for the sample.
Table 10. The size of the average bank in the sample, 1996
|
|
1996 |
Country |
Assets MECU |
Number of employees |
Belgium |
53 936 |
6 337 |
Denmark |
22 881 |
2 781 |
France |
127 002 |
25 431 |
Germany |
120 575 |
12 299 |
Italy |
48 151 |
13 018 |
The Netherlands |
11 342 |
25 528 |
Sweden |
22 842 |
3 240 |
UK |
81 790 |
28 344 |
The main bank- types represented are commercial banks (67),
The average bank in the sample had some 14 000 employees and a branch network of almost 700 branches.
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:299 |
|
|
|
3.5.2Empirical results
Here we report efficiency scores under both VRS and CRS, with two different choices of input variables and with the three output variables, loans, number of branch offices, and deposits.
Because the number of variables is small in this data set, one would expect rather low levels of efficiency and a large dispersion between best practice and average efficiency. This is in fact the case. There is a large variation in efficiency.
The results are shown in Figures
Figure 12. Country mean efficiency scores for European banks, 1996
|
0,70 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,50 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
efficiency |
0,40 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Mean |
0,30 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,20 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,10 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,00 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Italy |
Sweden |
Denmark |
UK |
France |
Belgium |
Germany |
Netherlands |
|
|
|
|
|
Country |
|
|
|
Figure 13 shows the efficiency distribution for the entire set of units.
Volym D:300 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Figure 13. The efficiency distribution of large European banks, 1996
|
1,00 |
|
|
0,90 |
|
|
0,80 |
|
|
|
|
|
0,70 |
|
|
0,60 |
|
Efficiency |
||
0,50 |
|
|
0,40 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
0,30 |
|
|
0,20 |
|
|
0,10 |
|
|
0,00 |
|
|
|
Units |
The number of frontier units in the base model
The distance between best practice and worst practice is unusually large, with three worst performing UK banks at the very bottom (efficiency score
The location of the Swedish banks in the base model is shown in Figure 14 and in the labour use model in Figure 15. The Swedish banks are spread along the entire efficiency distribution in the
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:301 |
|
|
|
Figure 14. The location of Swedish banks in the efficiency distribution of
European Banks, 1996, variable returns to scale
Input saving efficiency
1,00 |
S |
|
|
0,90 |
|
0,80 |
|
0,70 |
|
0,60 |
S |
0,50 |
S |
|
|
0,40 |
S |
0,30 |
S S |
0,20 |
S |
|
S |
0,10 |
S S |
0,00 |
S |
|
|
|
Units |
Figure 15. The location of Swedish banks in the
Efficiency |
|
|
1,00 |
|
|
0,90 |
|
|
0,80 |
|
|
0,70 |
|
|
0,60 |
|
|
0,50 |
|
|
0,40 |
|
S |
|
|
|
0,30 |
|
S |
0,20 |
|
S S |
|
S |
|
0,10 |
S S |
S |
S |
|
|
|
|
|
S |
S |
|
0,00 |
|
|
|
|
Units |
3.5.3Conclusions
There is a large variation in efficiency between banks, both within each country analysed and across countries. In a European perspective,
Volym D:302 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Swedish commercial banking efficiency on average ranks second from the bottom, both in a
It is difficult to know the impact on the efficiency distribution of including more variables, on the input side as well as the output side. Since we have no additional data for a sensitivity analysis, one should be cautious in interpreting the results.
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:303 |
|
|
|
References
Aigner, D., J. and S.F. Chu, (1968), ”On Estimating the Industry Production Function”, American Economic Review, 58,
Aigner, D., C.A.K. Lovell and P. Schmidt, (1977), ”Formulation and Estimation of Stochastic Frontier Production Function Models”,
Journal of Econometrics, 6,
Andersson I., (1999), ”Efficiency in European Banks”, Department of Economics, Göteborg University, Working paper.
Battese, G.E., (1997), ”A Note on the Estimation of
Battese, G.E., and T.J. Coelli, (1995), ”A Model for Technical Inefficiency Effects in a Stochastic Frontier Production Function for Panel Data”, Empirical Economics, 20,
Battese, G.E., Heshmati, A. and L. Hjalmarsson, (1997), ”Efficiency of Labour Use in the Swedish Banking Industry: A Stochastic Frontier Approach”, Paper presented at The Fifth European Workshop on Efficiency and Productivity Analysis, Copenhagen, October
Berg, S.A., F.R. Førsund, L. Hjalmarsson and M. Suominen, (1993), ”Banking Efficiency in the Nordic Countries”, Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 17 Nos.
Berger, A. N. and D. Humphrey, (1992), ”Measurement and Efficiency Issues in Commercial Banking”, In: Z. Grilliches eds., ”Output Measurement in the Service Sectors”, University of Chicago Press:
Berger, A.N., and D.B. Humphrey, (1997), ”Efficiency of Financial Institutions: International Survey and Directions for Future Research”, European Journal of Operational Research, 98,
Bukh, P.N.D., S.A. Berg and F.R. Førsund, (1995), ”Banking Efficiency in the Nordic Countries: A
Caudill, S.B., and J.M. Ford, (1993), ”Biases in Frontier Estimation and
Caves, D., L. Christensen, and E. Diewert, (1982), ”The Ec onomic Theory of Index Numbers and the Measurement of Input, Output, and Productivity”, Econometrica, 50 (6),
Volym D:304 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Charnes, A., W.W Cooper and E. Rhodes, (1978), ”Measuring The Efficiency of Decision Making Units”, European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 2, No. 2,
Coelli, T.J., (1996), ”A Guide to FRONTIER Version 4.1: A Computer Program for Frontier Production Function Estimation”, CEPA Working Paper 96/07, Department of Econometrics, University of New England, Armidale.
Colwell, R.J, and E.P. Davis, (1992), ”Output and Productivity in Banking”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, (Supplement),
Farrell, M., J., (1957), ”The Measurement of Productive Efficiency”,
Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A, 120 (III),
Fixler, D.J. and K.D . Zieschang, (1992), ”User Costs, Shadow Prices, and the Real Output of Banks” In: Zvi Grilliches eds., ”Output Measurement in the Service Sectors”, University of Chicago Press,
Färe, R., S. Grosskopf, B. Lindgren, and P. Roos, ( 1994), ”Productivity Developments in Swedish Hospitals: A Malmquist Output Index Approach”, in A. Charnes, W.W. Cooper, A.Y. Lewin, and L.M. Selford (eds.), Data Envelopment Analysis: Theory, Methodology and Applications, Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson, (1974), ”On the Measurement of Productive Efficiency”, Swedish Journal of Economics 76,
Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson, (1979a), ”Frontier Production Functions and Technical Progress: A study of General Milk Processing in Swedish Dairy Plants”, Econometrica, vol. 47, (4),
Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson, (1979b), ”Generalised Farrell Measures of Efficiency: An Application to Milk Processing in Swedish Dairy Plants”, Economical Journal, vol. 89,
Førsund, F.R., L. Hjalmarsson and T. Summa, (1996), ”The Interplay between the Micro Frontier and
Greene W.H., (1993), ”The Ec onometric Approach to Efficiency Analysis”, in The Measurement of Productive Efficiency; Techniques and Applications, eds., Fried, H., in eds.,Fried, H., The Measurement of Productive Efficiency: Techniques and Applications.
Grosskopf, S., (1996), ”Statistical Inference and Nonparametric Efficiency: A Selective Survey”, Journal of Productivity Analysis, vol. 7,
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:305 |
|
|
|
Heshmati, A., (1997), ”Labor Demand,
Hjalmarsson, L., (1973), ”Optimal Structural Change and Related Concepts”, Swedish Journal of Economics, 75,
Hjalmarsson, L., Bjurek, H., and A. Isaksson, (1991), ”Produktivitets- utveckling och effektivitet inom svensk bankverksamhet”, In
Produktivitet i vissa tjänstesektorer , Expertrapport nr 2 till Produktivitetsdelegationen, Allmänna Förlaget.
Hoover, A.D., (1998), ”Swedish Savings Banks: A Sector Analysis of Labor Cost Efficiency Using Stochastic Frontier Analysis with Panel Data”, Department of Economics, Göteborg University Working paper, 1998.
Humphrey D., (1984), ”The U.S. Payment System, Costs Pricing, Competition and Risk”, Monograph Series in Finance and Economics, Solomon Bros Centre for Study of Financial Industry, NY.
Kumbhakar S., Heshmati, A. and L. Hjalmarsson, (1999), ”Parametric Approaches to Productivity Measurement: A Comparison Among Alternative Models”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics,101(3),
Kumbhakar S., Heshmati, A. and L. Hjalmarsson, (1998), ”How Fast Do Banks Adjust? A Dynamic Model of
Lovell, C.A.K., (1993), ”Production Frontiers and Productive Efficiency”, in The Measurement of Productive Efficiency; Techniques and Applications, eds., Fried, H., in eds., Fried, H., The Measurement of Productive Efficiency: Techniques and Applications.
Malmquist, S., (1953), ”Index Numbers and Indifference Surfaces”,
Trabajos de Estatistica, 4,
Meeusen, W. and J. van den Broeck,(1977), ”Efficiency Estimation from
International Economic Review, 18,
Mester L. J., (1997), ”Measuring efficiency at U.S. Banks: Accounting for heterogeneity is important”, European Journal of Operational Research, 98 (2),
Volym D:306 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Nishimizu, M and Page, J., M., (1982), ”Total factor productivity growth, technological progress and technical efficiency change: Dimensions of productivity change in Yugoslavia
Economic Journal 92,
Richmond, J., (1974), ”Estimating the Efficiency of Production”,
International Economic Review, 15,
Sherman, J.D. and F. Gold, (1985), ”Bank Branch Operating Efficiency: Evaluation with Data Envelopment Analysis”, Journal of Banking and Finance 9.
Triplett , J.E., (1992), ”Comments on "Measurements and Efficiency in Banking”, by A.N. Berger and D. Humphrey In: Zvi Grilliches eds., ”Output measurement in the service sectors”, University of Chicago Press.
Tulkens, H., (1993), ”On FDH Efficiency Analysis: Some Methodological Issues and Applications to Retail Banking, Courts and Urban Transit”, Journal of Productivity Analysis, 4:
Vassiloglou, M. and D. Giokas, (1990), ”A study of the Relative Efficiency of Bank Branches: An application of data envelopment analysis”, Journal of operational research society, 41,
Wykoff, F. C., (1992), ”Comments on measurements and efficiency in banking”, In: Z. Grilliches ed., ”Output measurement in the service sectors”, University of Chicago Press.
Zhang, Y., and R. Bartels, (1998), ”The effect of sample size on the mean efficiency in DEA with an application to electricity distribution in Australia, Sweden and New Zealand”, Journal of Productivity Analysis, 9 (3),
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:307 |
|
|
|
Appendix 1
The stochastic frontier model
We assume that the following translog stochastic frontier model defines labour use for the 156 banks in our data
ln Y |
= |
0 |
+ * D |
+ |
6 |
j |
x |
jit |
+ 6 6 |
jk |
x |
jit |
x |
kit |
+V + U |
it |
(1) |
it |
|
0 it |
|
j=1 |
|
j k =1 |
|
|
it |
|
|||||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
where the subscripts i and t represent the
Y represents the total quantity of labour used (in hours per year);
D is a dummy variable for guarantees, which has value one if guarantees were zero or not observed, and, otherwise zero 4
x1 is the logarithm of the total amount of public loans (in SEK1,000);
x2 is the logarithm of the maximum of the guarantees (in SEK1,000);
x3 is the logarithm of deposits (in SEK1,000);
x4 is the logarithm of the number of branches;
x5 is the logarithm of the value of machinery and equipment;
x6 is the year of observation, where x6 = 1, 2, …, 12;
the Vits are random variables, associated with measurement errors in the labour variable or the effects of unspecified explanatory variables in the model, which are assumed to be independent and identically distributed with N(0,
The Uits are
4 Some small banks had zero guarantees. This variable permits the intercepts to be different for banks with positive and zero guarantees, see Battese (1997).
Volym D:308 |
Supplement 28 |
|
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
|
|
µit = 0 |
+ å4 0j Djit + |
å4 j zjit |
(2) |
|
j=1 |
j=1 |
|
where |
D1, D2, D3, and D4 are dummy variables which have value one if |
||
the observation involved is on a bank of types 1, 2, 3, and 4, |
|
||
respectively, and, otherwise zero; |
|
z1 is the logarithm of the number of branches (i.e., z1 = x4);
z2 is the logarithm of total machinery and equipment (i.e., z2
= x5);
z3 is the year of observation (i.e., z3 = x6); and
z4 is the square of the year of observation (i.e., z4 = z32).
The model incorporates
The specification of the model for the inefficiency effects in equation
(2) implies, in addition to accounting for the existence of inefficiency effects in the use of labour in producing outputs that the variations in the inefficiency effects are a function of other variables. In this case, we permit the level of the inefficiency effects in labour use to be different for five different types of banks (associated with the four dummy variables for types of banks), and they also depend on the number of branches in the banks and the year of observation.
The parameters of the stochastic frontier model, defined by equations
(1) and (2), were simultaneously estimated by the method of maximum likelihood using the computer program, FRONTIER 4.1, written by Coelli (1996).
The technical efficiency of labour use for the
TEit = |
(3) |
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:309 |
|
|
|
which indicates that technical efficiency is no greater than one. The reciprocal of this quantity, exp(Uit), is no less than one, and can be interpreted as a measure of the technical inefficiency of labour use.5
Computation of efficiency scores by DEA
The
min E1k |
|
|
k |
|
|
subject to the following restrictions: |
(4) |
|
yrk åNj kj |
yrj , r = 1,...,m |
(4a) |
E1k xik åNj |
kj xij , i = 1,...,n |
|
åNj kj = 1 |
|
(4b) |
kj 0, j = 1,...,N |
(4c) |
where E1k is the
Restriction (4a) implies that the reference plant must produce at least as much as plant k, while restriction (4b) implies that the efficiency- adjusted volume of input used by plant k must at least amount to the input volume used by the reference plant. Restriction (4c) is the condition for VRS. If this restriction is omitted, CRS is implied; E1 and E2 then coincide with each other.
5 More precisely, the amount by which exp(Uit) exceeds one is a measure of technical inefficiency of
Volym D:310 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
Appendix 2
The selection of large European banks
SWEDEN
Stadshypotek Wasabanken Sparbanken Föreningsbanken Tryggbanken Skandiabanken JP Bank
Östgöta Banken Nordbanken Handelsbanken
GERMANY
Depfa Bank
Deutsche Bank
Bayerische Hypotheken und Wechsel Bank
Landesbank Schleswig Holstein
Stadtsparkasse Köln
Hamburger Sparkasse
Dresdner Bank
DG Bank
Commerzbank
Bayerische Stadtsparkasse
BHF Bank
Hamburgerische Landesbank
West LB
SGZ Bank
Bankgesellschaft Berlin
DSL Bank
Deutsche Ausgleichbank
Vereinsbank
Nord LB
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:311 |
|
|
|
Deutsche Girocentrale
Frankfurter Sparkasse
ITALY
Cassa di Risparmio di Verona
Banca Commerciale Italiana
Banca Ambrosiano Veneto
Cassa diRisparmio di Parma et Piacenza
Banca Populare di Novara
Banca Nazionale di Lavoro
Rolo Banca
Cassa di Risparmio
Credito Italiano
Banca di Roma
Banca Nazionale di Agricultura
Medio Banca
Banca Agricola di Mantova
Istituto Bancarioi di San Paolo
Istituto Mobiliare Italiana
Cassa di Risparmio di Firenze
Banca Monte Paschi di Siena
GREAT BRITAIN
Flemings Bank
Schröders
Lloyds Bank
HSBC
Moscow Norodny Bank
Standard Chartered Bank
The Royal Bank of Scotland
Nationwide
Bradford and Bingley
Abbey National
Hambros
Northern Rock
Nikko Bank
Barclays Bank
Bank of Scotland
National Westminster Bank
Volym D:312 Supplement 28 |
SOU 2000:11 |
|
|
THE NETHERLANDS
ING
ABN
De Nationale Investeringsbank N.V.
Bank Nederlandske Gemeenten
SNS
DENMARK
Arbejdernes Landesbank
Sydbank
Bikuben
Realkredit
Jyske Bank
BRF Kredit
Den Danske Bank
Unidanmark
Nykredit Bank
BELGIUM
CERA Bank
ANHYP
IPPA Bank
Generale Bank
BBL
Kredietbank
Bank van Roeselare
Bacob Bank
Crédit à L= Industrie
DEXIA
FRANCE
Banques Populaires
Credit Locale de France
SOVAC
Credit Lyonnais
Credit Mutuel
Société Générale
Caisse de Depot Group
SOU 2000:11 |
Swedish Banking Efficiency and Productivity… |
Volym D:313 |
|
|
|
Banque Parisbas
Crédit Immobilier
Banque Worms
Banque Nationale de Paris
Banque Indosuez
Crédit Agricole
Crédit Commerciale de France